Package 'REAT'

Title: Regional Economic Analysis Toolbox
Description: Collection of models and analysis methods used in regional and urban economics and (quantitative) economic geography, e.g. measures of inequality, regional disparities and convergence, regional specialization as well as accessibility and spatial interaction models.
Authors: Thomas Wieland
Maintainer: Thomas Wieland <[email protected]>
License: GPL (>= 2)
Version: 3.0.3
Built: 2024-12-01 08:46:59 UTC
Source: CRAN

Help Index


Regional Economic Analysis Toolbox

Description

In regional and urban economics and economic geography, very frequent research fields are the existence and evolution of agglomerations due to (internal and external) agglomeration economies, regional economic growth and regional disparities, where these concepts and relationships are closely related to each other (Capello/Nijkamp 2009, Dinc 2015, Farhauer/Kroell 2013, McCann/van Oort 2009). Also accessibility and spatial interaction modeling is mostly regarded as related to these disciplines (Aoyama et al. 2011, Guessefeldt 1999). The group of the related analysis methods is sometimes summarized by the term regional analysis or regional economic analysis (Dinc 2015, Guessefeldt 1999, Isard 1960).

This package contains a collection of models and analysis methods used in regional and urban economics and (quantitative) economic geography. The functions in this package can be divided into seven groups:

(1) Inequality, concentration and dispersion, including Gini coefficient, Lorenz curve, Herfindahl-Hirschman-coefficient, Theil coefficient, Hoover coefficient and (weighted) coefficient of variation

(2) Specialization of regions and spatial concentration of industries, including location quotient, spatial Gini coefficients for regional specialization and industry concentration and Krugman coefficients for regional specialization and industry concentration

(3) Regional disparities and regional convergence, especially analysis of beta and sigma convergence for cross-sectional data

(4) Regional growth, including portfolio matrix, several types of shift-share analysis and commercial area prognosis ("GIFPRO")

(5) Spatial interaction and accessibility models, including Huff model and Hansen accessibility

(6) Proximity analysis, including calculation of distance matrices and buffers

(7) Additional tools for data preparation und visualization, such as for creating dummy variables and calculating standardized regression coefficients. The package also contains data examples.

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

Maintainer: Thomas Wieland [email protected]

References

Aoyama, Y./Murphy, J. T./Hanson, S. (2011): “Key Concepts in Economic Geography”. London: SAGE.

Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (2009): “Introduction: regional growth and development theories in the twenty-first century - recent theoretical advances and future challenges”. In: Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (eds.): Handbook of Regional Growth and Development Theories. Cheltenham: Elgar. p. 1-16.

Dinc, M. (2015): “Introduction to Regional Economic Development. Major Theories and Basic Analytical Tools”. Cheltenham: Elgar.

Farhauer, O./Kroell, A. (2013): “Standorttheorien: Regional- und Stadtoekonomik in Theorie und Praxis”. Wiesbaden: Springer.

Guessefeldt, J. (1999): “Regionalanalyse”. Muenchen: Oldenbourg.

Isard, W. (1960): “Methods of Regional Analysis: an Introduction to Regional Science”. Cambridge: M.I.T. Press.

McCann, P./van Oort, F. (2009): “Theories of agglomeration and regional economic growth: a historical review”. In: Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (eds.): Handbook of Regional Growth and Development Theories. Cheltenham: Elgar. p. 19-32.


Atkinson Inequality Index

Description

Calculating the Atkinson Inequality Index e.g. with respect to regional income

Usage

atkinson(x, epsilon = 0.5, na.rm = TRUE)

Arguments

x

A numeric vector (e.g. dataset of regional income)

epsilon

A single value of the ϵ\epsilon weighting coefficient (default: at.epsilon = 0.5)

na.rm

logical argument that indicates whether NA values should be excluded before computing results

Details

The Atkinson Inequality Index (AIAI) varies between 0 (no inequality/concentration) and 1 (complete inequality/concentration). It can be used for economic inequality and/or regional disparities (Portnov/Felsenstein 2010).

Value

A single numeric value of the Atkinson Inequality Index (0<AI<10 < AI < 1).

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Portnov, B.A./Felsenstein, D. (2010): “On the suitability of income inequality measures for regional analysis: Some evidence from simulation analysis and bootstrapping tests”. In: Socio-Economic Planning Sciences, 44, 4, p. 212-219.

See Also

cv, gini, gini2, herf, theil, hoover, coulter, dalton, disp

Examples

atkinson(c(100,0,0,0), epsilon = 0.8)

atkinson(c(100,100,100,100), epsilon = 0.8)

Automotive industry data

Description

Top 20 automotive industry companies, including their manufacturing quantity and turnovers (Table from wikipedia)

Usage

data("Automotive")

Format

A data frame with 20 observations on the following 8 variables.

Rank

Rank of the company

Company

Name of the company (German)

Country

Origin county of the company (German)

Quantity2014

Quantity of produced vehicles in 2014

Quantity2014_car

Quantity of produced cars in 2014

Turnover2008

Annual turnover 2008 (in billion dollars)

Turnover2012

Annual turnover 2012 (in billion dollars)

Turnover2013

Annual turnover 2013 (in billion dollars)

Source

Wikipedia (2018): “Automobilindustrie — Wikipedia, Die freie Enzyklopaedie”. https://de.wikipedia.org/wiki/Automobilindustrie (accessed October 14, 2018). Own postprocessing.

References

Wikipedia (2018): “Automobilindustrie — Wikipedia, Die freie Enzyklopaedie”. https://de.wikipedia.org/wiki/Automobilindustrie (accessed October 14, 2018).

Examples

# Market concentration in automotive industry

data(Automotive)

gini(Automotive$Turnover2008, lsize=1, lc=TRUE, le.col = "black", 
lc.col = "orange", lcx = "Shares of companies", lcy = "Shares of turnover / cars", 
lctitle = "Automotive industry: market concentration", 
lcg = TRUE, lcgn = TRUE, lcg.caption = "Turnover 2008:", lcg.lab.x = 0, lcg.lab.y = 1)
# Gini coefficient and Lorenz curve for turnover 2008

gini(Automotive$Turnover2013, lsize=1, lc = TRUE, add.lc = TRUE, lc.col = "red", 
lcg = TRUE, lcgn = TRUE, lcg.caption = "Turnover 2013:", lcg.lab.x = 0, lcg.lab.y = 0.85)
# Adding Gini coefficient and Lorenz curve for turnover 2013

gini(Automotive$Quantity2014_car, lsize=1, lc = TRUE, add.lc = TRUE, lc.col = "blue", 
lcg = TRUE, lcgn = TRUE, lcg.caption = "Cars 2014:", lcg.lab.x = 0, lcg.lab.y = 0.7)
# Adding Gini coefficient and Lorenz curve for cars 2014

Analysis of regional beta convergence using nonlinear regression

Description

This function provides the analysis of absolute and conditional regional economic beta convergence for cross-sectional data using a nonlineaer least squares (NLS) technique.

Usage

betaconv.nls(gdp1, time1, gdp2, time2, conditions = NULL, conditions.formula = NULL, 
conditions.startval = NULL, beta.plot = FALSE, beta.plotPSize = 1, 
beta.plotPCol = "black", beta.plotLine = FALSE, beta.plotLineCol = "red", 
beta.plotX = "Ln (initial)", beta.plotY = "Ln (growth)", 
beta.plotTitle = "Beta convergence", beta.bgCol = "gray95", beta.bgrid = TRUE, 
beta.bgridCol = "white", beta.bgridSize = 2, beta.bgridType = "solid", 
print.results = TRUE)

Arguments

gdp1

A numeric vector containing the GDP per capita (or another economic variable) at time t

time1

A single value of time t (= the initial year)

gdp2

A numeric vector containing the GDP per capita (or another economic variable) at time t+1 or a data frame containing the GDPs per capita (or another economic variable) at time t+1, t+2, t+3, ..., t+n

time2

A single value of time t+1 or t_n, respectively

conditions

A data frame containing the conditions for conditional beta convergence

conditions.formula

A formula for the functional linkage of the conditions in the case of conditional beta convergence

conditions.startval

Starting values for the parameters of the conditions in the case of conditional beta convergence

beta.plot

Boolean argument that indicates if a plot of beta convergence has to be created

beta.plotPSize

If beta.plot = TRUE: Point size in the beta convergence plot

beta.plotPCol

If beta.plot = TRUE: Point color in the beta convergence plot

beta.plotLine

If beta.plot = TRUE: Logical argument that indicates if a regression line has to be added to the plot

beta.plotLineCol

If beta.plot = TRUE and beta.plotLine = TRUE: Line color of regression line

beta.plotX

If beta.plot = TRUE: Name of the X axis

beta.plotY

If beta.plot = TRUE: Name of the Y axis

beta.plotTitle

If beta.plot = TRUE: Plot title

beta.bgCol

If beta.plot = TRUE: Plot background color

beta.bgrid

If beta.plot = TRUE: Logical argument that indicates if the plot contains a grid

beta.bgridCol

If beta.plot = TRUE and beta.bgrid = TRUE: Color of the grid

beta.bgridSize

If beta.plot = TRUE and beta.bgrid = TRUE: Size of the grid

beta.bgridType

If beta.plot = TRUE and beta.bgrid = TRUE: Type of the grid

print.results

Logical argument that indicates if the function shows the results or not

Details

From the regional economic perspective (in particular the neoclassical growth theory), regional disparities are expected to decline. This convergence can have different meanings: Sigma convergence (σ\sigma) means a harmonization of regional economic output or income over time, while beta convergence (β\beta) means a decline of dispersion because poor regions have a stronger economic growth than rich regions (Capello/Nijkamp 2009). Regardless of the theoretical assumptions of a harmonization in reality, the related analytical framework allows to analyze both types of convergence for cross-sectional data (GDP p.c. or another economic variable, yy, for ii regions and two points in time, tt and t+Tt+T), or one starting point (tt) and the average growth within the following nn years (t+1,t+2,...,t+nt+1, t+2, ..., t+n), respectively. Beta convergence can be calculated either in a linearized OLS regression model or in a nonlinear regression model. When no other variables are integrated in this model, it is called absolute beta convergence. Implementing other region-related variables (conditions) into the model leads to conditional beta convergence. If there is beta convergence (β<0\beta < 0), it is possible to calculate the speed of convergence, λ\lambda, and the so-called Half-Life HH, while the latter is the time taken to reduce the disparities by one half (Allington/McCombie 2007, Goecke/Huether 2016). There is sigma convergence, when the dispersion of the variable (σ\sigma), e.g. calculated as standard deviation or coefficient of variation, reduces from tt to t+Tt+T. This can be measured using ANOVA for two years or trend regression with respect to several years (Furceri 2005, Goecke/Huether 2016).

This function calculates absolute and/or conditional beta convergence using a nonlinear least squares approach for estimation. It needs at least two vectors (GDP p.c. or another economic variable, yy, for ii regions) and the related two points in time (tt and t+Tt+T). If the beta coefficient is negative (using OLS) or positive (using NLS), there is beta convergence.

Value

A list containing the following objects:

regdata

A data frame containing the regression data, including the lnln-transformed economic variables

abeta

A list containing the estimates of the absolute beta convergence regression model, including lambda and half-life

cbeta

If conditions are stated: a list containing the estimates of the conditional beta convergence regression model, including lambda and half-life

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Allington, N. F. B./McCombie, J. S. L. (2007): “Economic growth and beta-convergence in the East European Transition Economies”. In: Arestis, P./Baddely, M./McCombie, J. S. L. (eds.): Economic Growth. New Directions in Theory and Policy. Cheltenham: Elgar. p. 200-222.

Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (2009): “Introduction: regional growth and development theories in the twenty-first century - recent theoretical advances and future challenges”. In: Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (eds.): Handbook of Regional Growth and Development Theories. Cheltenham: Elgar. p. 1-16.

Dapena, A. D./Vazquez, E. F./Morollon, F. R. (2016): “The role of spatial scale in regional convergence: the effect of MAUP in the estimation of beta-convergence equations”. In: The Annals of Regional Science, 56, 2, p. 473-489.

Furceri, D. (2005): “Beta and sigma-convergence: A mathematical relation of causality”. In: Economics Letters, 89, 2, p. 212-215.

Goecke, H./Huether, M. (2016): “Regional Convergence in Europe”. In: Intereconomics, 51, 3, p. 165-171.

Young, A. T./Higgins, M. J./Levy, D. (2008): “Sigma Convergence versus Beta Convergence: Evidence from U.S. County-Level Data”. In: Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 40, 5, p. 1083-1093.

See Also

rca, betaconv.ols, betaconv.speed, sigmaconv, sigmaconv.t, cv, sd2, var2

Examples

data (G.counties.gdp)
# Loading GDP data for Germany (counties = Landkreise)
betaconv.nls (G.counties.gdp$gdppc2010, 2010, G.counties.gdp$gdppc2011, 2011, 
conditions = NULL, print.results = TRUE)
# Two years, no conditions (Absolute beta convergence)

Analysis of regional beta convergence using OLS regression

Description

This function provides the analysis of absolute and conditional regional economic beta convergence for cross-sectional data using ordinary least squares (OLS) technique.

Usage

betaconv.ols(gdp1, time1, gdp2, time2, conditions = NULL, beta.plot = FALSE, 
beta.plotPSize = 1, beta.plotPCol = "black", beta.plotLine = FALSE, 
beta.plotLineCol = "red", beta.plotX = "Ln (initial)", beta.plotY = "Ln (growth)", 
beta.plotTitle = "Beta convergence", beta.bgCol = "gray95", beta.bgrid = TRUE,
beta.bgridCol = "white", beta.bgridSize = 2, beta.bgridType = "solid", 
print.results = FALSE)

Arguments

gdp1

A numeric vector containing the GDP per capita (or another economic variable) at time t

time1

A single value of time t (= the initial year)

gdp2

A numeric vector containing the GDP per capita (or another economic variable) at time t+1 or a data frame containing the GDPs per capita (or another economic variable) at time t+1, t+2, t+3, ..., t+n

time2

A single value of time t+1 or t_n, respectively

conditions

A data frame containing the conditions for conditional beta convergence

beta.plot

Boolean argument that indicates if a plot of beta convergence has to be created

beta.plotPSize

If beta.plot = TRUE: Point size in the beta convergence plot

beta.plotPCol

If beta.plot = TRUE: Point color in the beta convergence plot

beta.plotLine

If beta.plot = TRUE: Logical argument that indicates if a regression line has to be added to the plot

beta.plotLineCol

If beta.plot = TRUE and beta.plotLine = TRUE: Line color of regression line

beta.plotX

If beta.plot = TRUE: Name of the X axis

beta.plotY

If beta.plot = TRUE: Name of the Y axis

beta.plotTitle

If beta.plot = TRUE: Plot title

beta.bgCol

If beta.plot = TRUE: Plot background color

beta.bgrid

If beta.plot = TRUE: Logical argument that indicates if the plot contains a grid

beta.bgridCol

If beta.plot = TRUE and beta.bgrid = TRUE: Color of the grid

beta.bgridSize

If beta.plot = TRUE and beta.bgrid = TRUE: Size of the grid

beta.bgridType

If beta.plot = TRUE and beta.bgrid = TRUE: Type of the grid

print.results

Logical argument that indicates if the function shows the results or not

Details

From the regional economic perspective (in particular the neoclassical growth theory), regional disparities are expected to decline. This convergence can have different meanings: Sigma convergence (σ\sigma) means a harmonization of regional economic output or income over time, while beta convergence (β\beta) means a decline of dispersion because poor regions have a stronger economic growth than rich regions (Capello/Nijkamp 2009). Regardless of the theoretical assumptions of a harmonization in reality, the related analytical framework allows to analyze both types of convergence for cross-sectional data (GDP p.c. or another economic variable, yy, for ii regions and two points in time, tt and t+Tt+T), or one starting point (tt) and the average growth within the following nn years (t+1,t+2,...,t+nt+1, t+2, ..., t+n), respectively. Beta convergence can be calculated either in a linearized OLS regression model or in a nonlinear regression model. When no other variables are integrated in this model, it is called absolute beta convergence. Implementing other region-related variables (conditions) into the model leads to conditional beta convergence. If there is beta convergence (β<0\beta < 0), it is possible to calculate the speed of convergence, λ\lambda, and the so-called Half-Life HH, while the latter is the time taken to reduce the disparities by one half (Allington/McCombie 2007, Goecke/Huether 2016). There is sigma convergence, when the dispersion of the variable (σ\sigma), e.g. calculated as standard deviation or coefficient of variation, reduces from tt to t+Tt+T. This can be measured using ANOVA for two years or trend regression with respect to several years (Furceri 2005, Goecke/Huether 2016).

This function calculates absolute and/or conditional beta convergence using ordinary least squares regression (OLS) for estimation. It needs at least two vectors (GDP p.c. or another economic variable, yy, for ii regions) and the related two points in time (tt and t+Tt+T). If the beta coefficient is negative (using OLS) or positive (using NLS), there is beta convergence.

Value

A list containing the following objects:

regdata

A data frame containing the regression data, including the lnln-transformed economic variables

abeta

A list containing the estimates of the absolute beta convergence regression model, including lambda and half-life

cbeta

If conditions are stated: a list containing the estimates of the conditional beta convergence regression model, including lambda and half-life

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Allington, N. F. B./McCombie, J. S. L. (2007): “Economic growth and beta-convergence in the East European Transition Economies”. In: Arestis, P./Baddely, M./McCombie, J. S. L. (eds.): Economic Growth. New Directions in Theory and Policy. Cheltenham: Elgar. p. 200-222.

Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (2009): “Introduction: regional growth and development theories in the twenty-first century - recent theoretical advances and future challenges”. In: Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (eds.): Handbook of Regional Growth and Development Theories. Cheltenham: Elgar. p. 1-16.

Dapena, A. D./Vazquez, E. F./Morollon, F. R. (2016): “The role of spatial scale in regional convergence: the effect of MAUP in the estimation of beta-convergence equations”. In: The Annals of Regional Science, 56, 2, p. 473-489.

Furceri, D. (2005): “Beta and sigma-convergence: A mathematical relation of causality”. In: Economics Letters, 89, 2, p. 212-215.

Goecke, H./Huether, M. (2016): “Regional Convergence in Europe”. In: Intereconomics, 51, 3, p. 165-171.

Young, A. T./Higgins, M. J./Levy, D. (2008): “Sigma Convergence versus Beta Convergence: Evidence from U.S. County-Level Data”. In: Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 40, 5, p. 1083-1093.

See Also

rca, betaconv.nls, betaconv.speed, sigmaconv, sigmaconv.t, cv, sd2, var2

Examples

data (G.counties.gdp)

betaconv.ols (G.counties.gdp$gdppc2010, 2010, G.counties.gdp$gdppc2011, 2011, 
conditions = NULL, print.results = TRUE)
# Two years, no conditions (Absolute beta convergence)

regionaldummies <- to.dummy(G.counties.gdp$regional)
# Creating dummy variables for West/East
G.counties.gdp$West <- regionaldummies[,2]
G.counties.gdp$East <- regionaldummies[,1]
# Adding dummy variables to data

betaconv.ols (G.counties.gdp$gdppc2010, 2010, G.counties.gdp$gdppc2011, 2011, 
conditions = G.counties.gdp[c(70,71)], print.results = TRUE)
# Two years, with condition (dummy for West/East)
# (Absolute and conditional beta convergence)

betaconverg1 <- betaconv.ols (G.counties.gdp$gdppc2010, 2010, G.counties.gdp$gdppc2011, 2011,
conditions = G.counties.gdp[c(70,71)], print.results = TRUE)
# Store results in object
betaconverg1$cbeta$estimates
# Addressing estimates for the conditional beta model


betaconv.ols (G.counties.gdp$gdppc2010, 2010, G.counties.gdp[65:66], 2012, 
conditions = NULL, print.results = TRUE)
# Three years (2010-2012), no conditions (Absolute beta convergence)

betaconv.ols (G.counties.gdp$gdppc2010, 2010, G.counties.gdp[65:66], 2012, 
conditions = G.counties.gdp[c(70,71)], print.results = TRUE)
# Three years (2010-2012), with conditions (Absolute and conditional beta convergence)

betaconverg2 <- betaconv.ols (G.counties.gdp$gdppc2010, 2010, G.counties.gdp[65:66],
2012, conditions = G.counties.gdp[c(70,71)], print.results = TRUE)
# Store results in object
betaconverg2$cbeta$estimates
# Addressing estimates for the conditional beta model

Regional beta convergence: Convergence speed and half-life

Description

This function calculates the beta convergence speed and half-life based on a given beta value and time interval.

Usage

betaconv.speed(beta, tinterval, print.results = TRUE)

Arguments

beta

Beta value

tinterval

Time interval (in time units, such as years)

print.results

Logical argument that indicates if the function shows the results or not

Details

From the regional economic perspective (in particular the neoclassical growth theory), regional disparities are expected to decline. This convergence can have different meanings: Sigma convergence (σ\sigma) means a harmonization of regional economic output or income over time, while beta convergence (β\beta) means a decline of dispersion because poor regions have a stronger economic growth than rich regions (Capello/Nijkamp 2009). Regardless of the theoretical assumptions of a harmonization in reality, the related analytical framework allows to analyze both types of convergence for cross-sectional data (GDP p.c. or another economic variable, yy, for ii regions and two points in time, tt and t+Tt+T), or one starting point (tt) and the average growth within the following nn years (t+1,t+2,...,t+nt+1, t+2, ..., t+n), respectively. Beta convergence can be calculated either in a linearized OLS regression model or in a nonlinear regression model. When no other variables are integrated in this model, it is called absolute beta convergence. Implementing other region-related variables (conditions) into the model leads to conditional beta convergence. If there is beta convergence (β<0\beta < 0), it is possible to calculate the speed of convergence, λ\lambda, and the so-called Half-Life HH, while the latter is the time taken to reduce the disparities by one half (Allington/McCombie 2007, Goecke/Huether 2016). There is sigma convergence, when the dispersion of the variable (σ\sigma), e.g. calculated as standard deviation or coefficient of variation, reduces from tt to t+Tt+T. This can be measured using ANOVA for two years or trend regression with respect to several years (Furceri 2005, Goecke/Huether 2016).

This function calculates the speed of convergence, λ\lambda, and the Half-Life, HH, based on a given β\beta value and time interval.

Value

A matrix containing the following objects:

Lambda

Lambda value (convergence speed)

Half-Life

Half-life values

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Allington, N. F. B./McCombie, J. S. L. (2007): “Economic growth and beta-convergence in the East European Transition Economies”. In: Arestis, P./Baddely, M./McCombie, J. S. L. (eds.): Economic Growth. New Directions in Theory and Policy. Cheltenham: Elgar. p. 200-222.

Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (2009): “Introduction: regional growth and development theories in the twenty-first century - recent theoretical advances and future challenges”. In: Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (eds.): Handbook of Regional Growth and Development Theories. Cheltenham: Elgar. p. 1-16.

Dapena, A. D./Vazquez, E. F./Morollon, F. R. (2016): “The role of spatial scale in regional convergence: the effect of MAUP in the estimation of beta-convergence equations”. In: The Annals of Regional Science, 56, 2, p. 473-489.

Furceri, D. (2005): “Beta and sigma-convergence: A mathematical relation of causality”. In: Economics Letters, 89, 2, p. 212-215.

Goecke, H./Huether, M. (2016): “Regional Convergence in Europe”. In: Intereconomics, 51, 3, p. 165-171.

Young, A. T./Higgins, M. J./Levy, D. (2008): “Sigma Convergence versus Beta Convergence: Evidence from U.S. County-Level Data”. In: Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 40, 5, p. 1083-1093.

See Also

betaconv.nls, betaconv.ols, sigmaconv, sigmaconv.t, cv, sd2, var2

Examples

speed <- betaconv.speed(-0.008070533, 1)
speed[1] # lambda
speed[2] # half-life

Measures of industry concentration

Description

Calculating three measures of industry concentration (Gini, Krugman, Hoover) for a set of II industries

Usage

conc(e_ij, industry.id, region.id, na.rm = TRUE)

Arguments

e_ij

a numeric vector with the employment of the industry ii in region jj

industry.id

a vector containing the IDs of the industries ii

region.id

a vector containing the IDs of the regions jj

na.rm

logical argument that indicates whether NA values should be excluded before computing results

Details

This function is a convenient wrapper for all functions calculating measures of spatial concentration of industries (Gini, Krugman, Hoover)

Value

A matrix with three columns (Gini coefficient, Krugman coefficient, Hoover coefficient) and II rows (one for each regarded industry).

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Farhauer, O./Kroell, A. (2014): “Standorttheorien: Regional- und Stadtoekonomik in Theorie und Praxis”. Wiesbaden : Springer.

Schaetzl, L. (2000): “Wirtschaftsgeographie 2: Empirie”. Paderborn : Schoeningh.

See Also

gini.conc, krugman.conc2, hoover

Examples

data(G.regions.industries)

conc_i <- conc (e_ij = G.regions.industries$emp_all, 
industry.id = G.regions.industries$ind_code,
region.id = G.regions.industries$region_code)

Breaking point formula by Converse

Description

Calculating the breaking point between two cities or retail locations

Usage

converse(P_a, P_b, D_ab)

Arguments

P_a

a single numeric value of attractivity/population size of location/city aa

P_b

a single numeric value of attractivity/population size of location/city bb

D_ab

a single numeric value of the transport costs (e.g. distance) between aa and bb

Details

The breaking point formula by Converse (1949) is a modification of the law of retail gravitation by Reilly (1929, 1931) (see the functions reilly and reilly.lambda). The aim of the calculation is to determine the boundaries of the market areas between two locations/cities in consideration of their attractivity/population size and the transport costs (e.g. distance) between them. The models by Reilly and Converse are simple spatial interaction models and are considered as deterministic market area models due to their exact allocation of demand origins to locations. A probabilistic approach including a theoretical framework was developed by Huff (1962) (see the function huff).

Value

a list with two values (B_a: distance from location aa to breaking point, B_b: distance from location bb to breaking point)

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Berman, B. R./Evans, J. R. (2012): “Retail Management: A Strategic Approach”. 12th edition. Bosten : Pearson.

Converse, P. D. (1949): “New Laws of Retail Gravitation”. In: Journal of Marketing, 14, 3, p. 379-384.

Huff, D. L. (1962): “Determination of Intra-Urban Retail Trade Areas”. Los Angeles : University of California.

Levy, M./Weitz, B. A. (2012): “Retailing management”. 8th edition. New York : McGraw-Hill Irwin.

Loeffler, G. (1998): “Market areas - a methodological reflection on their boundaries”. In: GeoJournal, 45, 4, p. 265-272

Reilly, W. J. (1929): “Methods for the Study of Retail Relationships”. Studies in Marketing, 4. Austin : Bureau of Business Research, The University of Texas.

Reilly, W. J. (1931): “The Law of Retail Gravitation”. New York.

See Also

huff, reilly

Examples

# Example from Huff (1962):
converse (400000, 200000, 80)
# two cities (population 400.000 and 200.000 with a distance separating them of 80 miles)

Coulter Coefficient

Description

Calculating the Coulter Coefficient e.g. with respect to regional income

Usage

coulter(x, weighting = NULL, na.rm = TRUE)

Arguments

x

A numeric vector (e.g. dataset of regional income)

weighting

a weighting vector, e.g. population

na.rm

logical argument that indicates whether NA values should be excluded before computing results

Details

The Coulter Coefficient (CCCC) varies between 0 (no inequality/concentration) and 1 (complete inequality/concentration). It can be used for economic inequality and/or regional disparities (Portnov/Felsenstein 2010).

Value

A single numeric value of the Coulter Coefficient (0<CC<10 < CC < 1).

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Portnov, B.A./Felsenstein, D. (2010): “On the suitability of income inequality measures for regional analysis: Some evidence from simulation analysis and bootstrapping tests”. In: Socio-Economic Planning Sciences, 44, 4, p. 212-219.

See Also

cv, gini, gini2, herf, theil, hoover, atkinson, dalton, disp

Examples

bip <- c(400,400,400, 400, NA)
bev <- c(1,1,1,200, NA)
coulter(bip, bev)

Curve fitting

Description

Curve fitting (similar to SPSS and Excel)

Usage

curvefit(x, y, y.max = NULL, extrapol = NULL, 
plot.curves = TRUE, pcol = "black", ptype = 19, psize = 1,
lin.col = "blue", pow.col = "green", exp.col = "orange", logi.col = "red",
plot.title = "Curve fitting", plot.legend = TRUE,
xlab = "x", ylab = "y", y.min = NULL, ..., print.results = TRUE)

Arguments

x

a numeric vector containing the explanatory variable

y

a numeric vector containing the dependent variable

y.max

Optional: given maximum for the logistic regression function

extrapol

a single numeric value for how many x units the dependent variable y shall be extrapolated

plot.curves

Logical argument that indicates whether the curves shall be plotted or not

pcol

If plot.curves = TRUE: Point color

ptype

If plot.curves = TRUE: Point type (pch)

psize

If plot.curves = TRUE: Point size

lin.col

If plot.curves = TRUE: Color of linear regression line

pow.col

If plot.curves = TRUE: Color of power function regression line

exp.col

If plot.curves = TRUE: Color of exponential function regression line

logi.col

If plot.curves = TRUE: Color of logistic function regression line

plot.title

If plot.curves = TRUE: Plot title

plot.legend

If plot.curves = TRUE: Logical argument that indicates whether a legend is added to the plot or not

xlab

If plot.curves = TRUE: X axis label

ylab

If plot.curves = TRUE: Y axis label

y.min

Optional: Y axis minimum

...

Optional: other plot parameters

print.results

Logical argument that indicates whether the model results are shown or not

Details

Curve fitting for a given independent and dependent variable (y=f(x)y = f(x)). Similar to curve fitting in SPSS or Excel. Fitting of nonlinear regression models (power, exponential, logistic) via intrinsically linear models (Rawlings et al. 1998).

Value

A data frame containing the regression results (Parameters a and b, std. errors, t values, ...)

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Rawlings, J. O./Pantula, S. G./Dickey, D. A. (1998): “Applied Regression Analysis”. Springer. 2nd edition.

Examples

x <- 1:20
y <- 3-2*x
curvefit(x, y, plot.curves = TRUE)
# fit with plot
curvefit(x, y, extrapol=10, plot.curves = TRUE)
# fit and extrapolation with plot

x <- runif(20, min = 0, max = 100)
# some random data

# linear
y_resid <- runif(20, min = 0, max = 10)
# random residuals
y <- 3+(-0.112*x)+y_resid
curvefit(x, y)

# power
y_resid <- runif(20, min = 0.1, max = 0.2)
# random residuals
y <- 3*(x^-0.112)*y_resid
curvefit(x, y)

# exponential
y_resid <- runif(20, min = 0.1, max = 0.2)
# random residuals
y <- 3*exp(-0.112*x)*y_resid
curvefit(x, y)

# logistic
y_resid <- runif(20, min = 0.1, max = 0.2)
# random residuals
y <- 100/(1+exp(3+(-0.112*x)))*y_resid
curvefit(x, y)

Coefficient of variation

Description

Calculating the coefficient of variation (cv), standardized and non-standardized, weighted and non-weighted

Usage

cv (x, is.sample = TRUE, coefnorm = FALSE, weighting = NULL, 
wmean = FALSE, na.rm = TRUE)

Arguments

x

a numeric vector

is.sample

logical argument that indicates if the dataset is a sample or the population (default: is.sample = TRUE, so the denominator of variance is n1n-1)

coefnorm

logical argument that indicates if the function output is the standardized cv (0<v<10 < v* < 1) or not (0<v<0 < v < \infty) (default: coefnorm = FALSE)

weighting

a numeric vector containing weighting data to compute the weighted coefficient of variation (instead of the non-weighted cv)

wmean

logical argument that indicates if the weighted mean is used when calculating the weighted coefficient of variation

na.rm

logical argument that whether NA values should be extracted or not

Details

The coefficient of variation, vv, is a dimensionless measure of statistical dispersion (0<v<0 < v < \infty), based on variance and standard deviation, respectively. From a regional economic perspective, it is closely linked to the concept of sigma convergence (σ\sigma) which means a harmonization of regional economic output or income over time, while the other type of convergence, beta convergence (β\beta), means a decline of dispersion because poor regions have a stronger growth than rich regions (Capello/Nijkamp 2009). The cv allows to summarize regional disparities (e.g. disparities in regional GDP per capita) in one indicator and is more frequently used for this purpose than the standard deviation, especially in analyzing of σ\sigma convergence over a long period (e.g. Lessmann 2005, Huang/Leung 2009, Siljak 2015). But the cv can also be used for any other types of disparities or dispersion, such as disparities in supply (e.g. density of physicians or grocery stores).

The cv (variance, standard deviation) can be weighted by using a second weighting vector. As there is more than one way to weight measures of statistical dispersion, this function uses the formula for the weighted cv (vwv_w) from Sheret (1984). The cv can be standardized, while this function uses the formula for the standardized cv (vv*, with 0<v<10 < v* < 1) from Kohn/Oeztuerk (2013). The vector x is automatically treated as a sample (such as in the base sd function), so the denominator of variance is n1n-1, if it is not, set is.sample = FALSE.

Value

Single numeric value. If coefnorm = FALSE the function returns the non-standardized cv (0<v<0 < v < \infty). If coefnorm = TRUE the standardized cv (0<v<10 < v* < 1) is returned.

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Bahrenberg, G./Giese, E./Mevenkamp, N./Nipper, J. (2010): “Statistische Methoden in der Geographie. Band 1: Univariate und bivariate Statistik”. Stuttgart: Borntraeger.

Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (2009): “Introduction: regional growth and development theories in the twenty-first century - recent theoretical advances and future challenges”. In: Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (eds.): Handbook of Regional Growth and Development Theories. Cheltenham: Elgar. p. 1-16.

Lessmann, C. (2005): “Regionale Disparitaeten in Deutschland und ausgesuchten OECD-Staaten im Vergleich”. ifo Dresden berichtet, 3/2005. https://www.ifo.de/DocDL/ifodb_2005_3_25-33.pdf.

Huang, Y./Leung, Y. (2009): “Measuring Regional Inequality: A Comparison of Coefficient of Variation and Hoover Concentration Index”. In: The Open Geography Journal, 2, p. 25-34.

Kohn, W./Oeztuerk, R. (2013): “Statistik fuer Oekonomen. Datenanalyse mit R und SPSS”. Berlin: Springer.

Sheret, M. (1984): “The Coefficient of Variation: Weighting Considerations”. In: Social Indicators Research, 15, 3, p. 289-295.

Siljak, D. (2015): “Real Economic Convergence in Western Europe from 1995 to 2013”. In: International Journal of Business and Economic Development, 3, 3, p. 56-67.

See Also

gini, herf, hoover, rca

Examples

# Regional disparities / sigma convergence in Germany
data(G.counties.gdp)
# GDP per capita for German counties (Landkreise)
cvs <- apply (G.counties.gdp[54:68], MARGIN = 2, FUN = cv)
# Calculating cv for the years 2000-2014
years <- 2000:2014
plot(years, cvs, "l", ylim=c(0.3,0.6), xlab = "year", 
ylab = "CV of GDP per capita")
# Plot cv over time

Dalton Inequality Index

Description

Calculating the Dalton Inequality Index e.g. with respect to regional income

Usage

dalton(x, na.rm = TRUE)

Arguments

x

A numeric vector (e.g. dataset of regional income)

na.rm

logical argument that indicates whether NA values should be excluded before computing results

Details

The Dalton Inequality Index (δ\delta) can be used for economic inequality and/or regional disparities (Portnov/Felsenstein 2010).

Value

A single numeric value of the Dalton Inequality Index.

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Portnov, B.A./Felsenstein, D. (2010): “On the suitability of income inequality measures for regional analysis: Some evidence from simulation analysis and bootstrapping tests”. In: Socio-Economic Planning Sciences, 44, 4, p. 212-219.

See Also

cv, gini, gini2, herf, theil, hoover, coulter, dalton, disp

Examples

dalton (c(10,10,10,10))

dalton (c(10,0,0,0))

dalton (c(10,1,1,1))

Concentration/inequality/dispersion measures

Description

Calculating a set of concentration/inequality/dispersion measures

Usage

disp(x, weighting = NULL, at.epsilon = 0.5, na.rm = TRUE)

Arguments

x

a numeric vector or matrix or columns from a data frame

weighting

a weighting vector, e.g. population

at.epsilon

Weighting parameter ϵ\epsilon for the Atkinson index

na.rm

logical argument that indicates whether NA values should be excluded before computing results

Details

This function is a convenient wrapper for all functions calculating concentration/inequality measures.

Value

A matrix containing the concentration/inequality measures.

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Gluschenko, K. (2018): “Measuring regional inequality: to weight or not to weight?” In: Spatial Economic Analysis, 13, 1, p. 36-59.

Portnov, B.A./Felsenstein, D. (2010): “On the suitability of income inequality measures for regional analysis: Some evidence from simulation analysis and bootstrapping tests”. In: Socio-Economic Planning Sciences, 44, 4, p. 212-219.

See Also

atkinson, coulter, dalton, cv, gini2, herf, hoover, sd2, theil, williamson

Examples

data(Automotive)

disp(Automotive$Turnover2008)
disp(Automotive[4:8])

Counting points in a buffer

Description

Counting points within a buffer of a given distance with points with given coordinates

Usage

dist.buf(startpoints, sp_id, lat_start, lon_start, endpoints, ep_id, lat_end, lon_end, 
ep_sum = NULL, bufdist = 500, extract_local = TRUE, unit = "m")

Arguments

startpoints

A data frame containing the start points

sp_id

Column containing the IDs of the startpoints in the data frame startpoints

lat_start

Column containing the latitudes of the start points in the data frame startpoints

lon_start

Column containing the longitudes of the start points in the data frame startpoints

endpoints

A data frame containing the points to count

ep_id

Column containing the IDs of the points to count in the data frame endpoints

lat_end

Column containing the latitudes of the points to count in the data frame endpoints

lon_end

Column containing the longitudes of the points to count in the data frame endpoints

ep_sum

Column of an additional variable in the data frame endpoints to sum

bufdist

The buffer distance

extract_local

Logical argument that indicates if the start points should be included or not (default: TRUE)

unit

Unit of the buffer distance: unit="m" for meters, unit="km" for kilometers or unit="miles" for miles

Details

The function is based on the idea of a buffer analysis in GIS (Geographic Information System), e.g. to count the points of interest within a given buffer distance.

Value

The function returns a list containing:

count_table

A data.frame containing two columns: The start point IDs (from) and the number of counted points in the given buffer distance (count_location)

distmat

A data.frame containing the corresponding distance matrix wiht IxJI x J rows

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

de Lange, N. (2013): “Geoinformatik in Theorie und Praxis”. 3rd edition. Berlin : Springer Spektrum.

Krider, R. E./Putler, R. S. (2013): “Which Birds of a Feather Flock Together? Clustering and Avoidance Patterns of Similar Retail Outlets”. In: Geographical Analysis, 45, 2, p. 123-149

See Also

dist, dist.mat

Examples

citynames <- c("Goettingen", "Karlsruhe", "Freiburg")
lat <- c(51.556307, 49.009603, 47.9874)
lon <- c(9.947375, 8.417004, 7.8945)
citynames <- c("Goettingen", "Karlsruhe", "Freiburg")
cities <- data.frame(citynames, lat, lon)
dist.mat (cities, "citynames", "lat", "lon", cities, "citynames", "lat", "lon")
# Euclidean distance matrix (3 x 3 cities = 9 distances)
dist.buf (cities, "citynames", "lat", "lon", cities, "citynames", "lat", "lon", bufdist = 300000)
# Cities within 300 km

Euclidean distance between coordinates

Description

Calculation of the euclidean distance between two points with stated coordinates (lat, lon)

Usage

dist.calc(lat1, lon1, lat2, lon2, unit = "km")

Arguments

lat1

Latitude of the regarded start point

lon1

Longitude of the regarded start point

lat2

Latitude of the regarded end point

lon2

Longitude of the regarded end point

unit

Unit of the resulting distance: unit="m" for meters, unit="km" for kilometers or unit="miles" for miles

Value

A single numeric value

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

See Also

dist.buf, dist.mat

Examples

dist.calc(51.556307, 9.947375, 49.009603, 8.417004)
# about 304 kilometers

Euclidean distance matrix between points

Description

Calculation of an euclidean distance matrix between points with stated coordinates (lat, lon)

Usage

dist.mat(startpoints, sp_id, lat_start, lon_start, endpoints, ep_id, 
lat_end, lon_end, unit = "km")

Arguments

startpoints

A data frame containing the start points

sp_id

Column containing the IDs of the startpoints in the data frame startpoints

lat_start

Column containing the latitudes of the start points in the data frame startpoints

lon_start

Column containing the longitudes of the start points in the data frame startpoints

endpoints

A data frame containing the end points

ep_id

Column containing the IDs of the endpoints in the data frame endpoints

lat_end

Column containing the latitudes of the end points in the data frame endpoints

lon_end

Column containing the longitudes of the end points in the data frame endpoints

unit

Unit of the resulting distance: unit="m" for meters, unit="km" for kilometers or unit="miles" for miles

Details

The function calculates an euclidean distance matrix between points with stated coordinates (lat and lon). While mm start points and nn end points are given, the output is a linear mnm * n distance matrix.

Value

The function returns a data.frame containing 4 columns: The start point IDs (from), the end point IDs (to), the combination of both (from_to) and the calculated distance (distance).

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

de Lange, N. (2013): “Geoinformatik in Theorie und Praxis”. 3rd edition. Berlin : Springer Spektrum.

Krider, R. E./Putler, R. S. (2013): “Which Birds of a Feather Flock Together? Clustering and Avoidance Patterns of Similar Retail Outlets”. In: Geographical Analysis, 45, 2, p. 123-149

See Also

dist, dist.buf

Examples

citynames <- c("Goettingen", "Karlsruhe", "Freiburg")
lat <- c(51.556307, 49.009603, 47.9874)
lon <- c(9.947375, 8.417004, 7.8945)
citynames <- c("Goettingen", "Karlsruhe", "Freiburg")
cities <- data.frame(citynames, lat, lon)
dist.mat (cities, "citynames", "lat", "lon", cities, "citynames", "lat", "lon")
# Euclidean distance matrix (3 x 3 cities = 9 distances)
dist.buf (cities, "citynames", "lat", "lon", cities, "citynames", "lat", "lon", bufdist = 300000)
# Cities within 300 km

Relative diversity index by Duranton and Puga

Description

Calculating the relative diversity index (RDI) by Duranton and Puga based on regional industry data (normally employment data)

Usage

durpug(e_ij, e_i)

Arguments

e_ij

a numeric vector with the employment of the industries ii in region jj

e_i

a numeric vector with the all-over employment in the industries ii

Value

A single numeric value of RDIRDI

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Duranton, G./Puga, D. (2000): “Diversity and Specialisation in Cities: Why, Where and When Does it Matter?”. In: Urban Studies, 37, 3, p. 533-555.

Farhauer, O./Kroell, A. (2013): “Standorttheorien: Regional- und Stadtoekonomik in Theorie und Praxis”. Wiesbaden : Springer.

See Also

gini.spec, krugman.spec, hoover

Examples

# Example Goettingen:

data(Goettingen)
# Loads the data

durpug (Goettingen$Goettingen2008[2:13], Goettingen$BRD2008[2:13])
# Returns the Duranton-Puga RDI for Goettingen

Ellison-Glaeser Agglomeration Index

Description

Calculating the Agglomeration Index by Ellison and Glaeser for a single industry ii

Usage

ellison.a(e_ik, e_j, regions, print.results = TRUE)

Arguments

e_ik

a numeric vector containing the no. of employees of firm kk from industry ii

e_j

a numeric vector containing the no. of employees in the regions jj

regions

a vector containing the IDs/names of the regions jj

print.results

logical argument that indicates whether the function prints the results or not (only for internal use)

Details

The Ellison-Glaeser Agglomeration Index is not standardized. A value of γi=0\gamma_i = 0 indicates a spatial distribution of firms equal to a dartboard approach. Values below zero indicate spatial dispersion, values greater than zero indicate clustering.

Value

A matrix with five columns (γi\gamma_i, GiG_i, zGiz_{G_i}, KiK_i and HHIiHHI_i).

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Ellison G./Glaeser, E. (1997): “Geographic concentration in u.s. manufacturing industries: A dartboard approach”. In: Journal of Political Economy, 105, 5, p. 889-927.

Farhauer, O./Kroell, A. (2014): “Standorttheorien: Regional- und Stadtoekonomik in Theorie und Praxis”. Wiesbaden : Springer.

Nakamura R./Morrison Paul, C. (2009): “Measuring agglomeration”. In: Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (eds): Handbook of Regional Growth and Development Theories, p. 305-328.

See Also

gini.conc, gini.spec, locq, locq2, howard.cl, howard.xcl, howard.xcl2, litzenberger, litzenberger2

Examples

# Example from Farhauer/Kroell (2014):
j <- c("Wien", "Wien", "Wien", "Wien", "Wien", "Linz", 
"Linz", "Linz", "Linz", "Graz")
E_ik <- c(200,650,12000,100,50,16000,13000,1500,1500,25000)
E_j <- c(500000,400000,100000)
ellison.a(E_ik, E_j, j)
# 0.05990628

Ellison-Glaeser Agglomeration Index

Description

Calculating the Agglomeration Index by Ellison and Glaeser for a given number of II industries

Usage

ellison.a2(e_ik, industry, region, print.results = TRUE)

Arguments

e_ik

a numeric vector containing the no. of employees of firm kk from industry ii

industry

a vector containing the IDs/names of the industries ii

region

a vector containing the IDs/names of the regions jj

print.results

logical argument that indicates whether the function prints the results or not (only for internal use)

Details

The Ellison-Glaeser Agglomeration Index is not standardized. A value of γi=0\gamma_i = 0 indicates a spatial distribution of firms equal to a dartboard approach. Values below zero indicate spatial dispersion, values greater than zero indicate clustering.

Value

A matrix with five columns (γi\gamma_i, GiG_i, zGiz_{G_i}, KiK_i and HHIiHHI_i) and II rows (one for each industry).

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Ellison G./Glaeser, E. (1997): “Geographic concentration in u.s. manufacturing industries: A dartboard approach”. In: Journal of Political Economy, 105, 5, p. 889-927.

Farhauer, O./Kroell, A. (2014): “Standorttheorien: Regional- und Stadtoekonomik in Theorie und Praxis”. Wiesbaden : Springer.

Nakamura R./Morrison Paul, C. (2009): “Measuring agglomeration”. In: Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (eds): Handbook of Regional Growth and Development Theories, p. 305-328.

See Also

ellison.a, gini.conc, gini.spec, locq, locq2, howard.cl, howard.xcl, howard.xcl2, litzenberger, litzenberger2

Examples

# Example data from Farhauer/Kroell (2014):
data(FK2014_EGC)

ellison.a2 (FK2014_EGC$emp_firm, FK2014_EGC$industry, 
FK2014_EGC$region)

Ellison-Glaeser Coagglomeration Index

Description

Calculating the Coagglomeration Index by Ellison and Glaeser for one set of UU industries

Usage

ellison.c(e_ik, industry, region, e_j = NULL, c.industries = NULL)

Arguments

e_ik

a numeric vector containing the no. of employees of firm kk from industry ii

industry

a vector containing the IDs/names of the industries ii

region

a vector containing the IDs/names of the regions jj

e_j

a numeric vector containing the total employment of the regions jj

c.industries

optional: a vector containing the regarded UU industries (where UIU \le I)

Details

The Ellison-Glaeser Coagglomeration Index is not standardized. A value of γc=0\gamma_c = 0 indicates a spatial distribution of firms equal to a dartboard approach. Values below zero indicate spatial dispersion, values greater than zero indicate clustering.

Value

A single value of γc\gamma_c

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Ellison G./Glaeser, E. (1997): “Geographic concentration in u.s. manufacturing industries: A dartboard approach”. In: Journal of Political Economy, 105, 5, p. 889-927.

Farhauer, O./Kroell, A. (2014): “Standorttheorien: Regional- und Stadtoekonomik in Theorie und Praxis”. Wiesbaden : Springer.

Nakamura R./Morrison Paul, C. (2009): “Measuring agglomeration”. In: Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (eds): Handbook of Regional Growth and Development Theories, p. 305-328.

See Also

ellison.a, ellison.a2, ellison.c2, gini.conc, gini.spec, locq, locq2, howard.cl, howard.xcl, howard.xcl2, litzenberger, litzenberger2

Examples

# Example from Farhauer/Kroell (2014):
data(FK2014_EGC)

ellison.c(FK2014_EGC$emp_firm, FK2014_EGC$industry, 
FK2014_EGC$region, FK2014_EGC$emp_region)

Ellison-Glaeser Coagglomeration Index

Description

Calculating the Coagglomeration Index by Ellison and Glaeser for IxIIxI sets of two industries

Usage

ellison.c2(e_ik, industry, region, e_j = NULL, print.results = TRUE)

Arguments

e_ik

a numeric vector containing the no. of employees of firm kk from industry ii

industry

a vector containing the IDs/names of the industries ii

region

a vector containing the IDs/names of the regions jj

e_j

a numeric vector containing the total employment of the regions jj

print.results

logical argument that indicates whether the results are printed or not (for internal use)

Details

The Ellison-Glaeser Coagglomeration Index is not standardized. A value of γc=0\gamma^c = 0 indicates a spatial distribution of firms equal to a dartboard approach. Values below zero indicate spatial dispersion, values greater than zero indicate clustering.

Value

A single value of γc\gamma^c

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Ellison G./Glaeser, E. (1997): “Geographic concentration in u.s. manufacturing industries: A dartboard approach”. In: Journal of Political Economy, 105, 5, p. 889-927.

Farhauer, O./Kroell, A. (2014): “Standorttheorien: Regional- und Stadtoekonomik in Theorie und Praxis”. Wiesbaden : Springer.

Nakamura R./Morrison Paul, C. (2009): “Measuring agglomeration”. In: Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (eds): Handbook of Regional Growth and Development Theories, p. 305-328.

See Also

ellison.a, ellison.a2, ellison.c, gini.conc, gini.spec, locq, locq2, howard.cl, howard.xcl, howard.xcl2, litzenberger, litzenberger2

Examples

# Example from Farhauer/Kroell (2014):
data(FK2014_EGC)

ellison.c2(FK2014_EGC$emp_firm, FK2014_EGC$industry, 
FK2014_EGC$region, FK2014_EGC$emp_region)
# this may take a while

Eurostat national employment data 2004-2016

Description

Employment data for EU countires 2004-2016 (Source: Eurostat)

Usage

data("EU28.emp")

Format

A data frame with 3000 observations on the following 7 variables.

unit

measuring unit: thousand persones (THS_PER)

nace_r2

NACE industry classification

s_adj

Adjustement of data: Not seasonally adjusted data (NSA)

na_item

a factor with levels SAL_DC

geo

NUTS nation code

time

year

emp1000

Industry-specific employment in thousand persons

Source

Eurostat (2018): Breakdowns of GDP aggregates and employment data by main industries and asset classes, Tab. code namq_10_a10_e. http://appsso.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/nui/show.do?dataset=namq_10_a10_e. Own postprocessing.

Examples

data(EU28.emp)
EU28.emp[EU28.emp$time == 2016,]
# only data for 2016

Fictional sample data of 42 firms

Description

Dataset with 42 firms from 4 industries in 3 regions (fictional sample data from Farhauer/Kroell 2014)

Usage

data("FK2014_EGC")

Format

A data frame with 42 observations on the following 5 variables.

region

unique ID of the region

industry

name of the industry (German language)

firm

firm ID

emp_firm

each firm's no. of employees

emp_region

total employment of the region

Source

Farhauer, O./Kroell, A. (2014): “Standorttheorien: Regional- und Stadtoekonomik in Theorie und Praxis”. Wiesbaden : Springer.

References

Farhauer, O./Kroell, A. (2014): “Standorttheorien: Regional- und Stadtoekonomik in Theorie und Praxis”. Wiesbaden : Springer.

Examples

# Example from Farhauer/Kroell (2014):
data(FK2014_EGC)

ellison.c(FK2014_EGC$emp_firm, FK2014_EGC$industry, 
FK2014_EGC$region, FK2014_EGC$emp_region)

Employment data in Freiburg and Germany

Description

Dataset with industry-specific employment in Freiburg and Germany in the years 2008 and 2014

Usage

data("Freiburg")

Format

A data frame with 9 observations on the following 8 variables.

industry

a factor with levels for the regarded industry based on the German official economic statistics (WZ2008)

e_Freiburg2008

a numeric vector with industry-specific employment in Freiburg 2008

e_Freiburg2014

a numeric vector with industry-specific employment in Freiburg 2014

e_g_Freiburg_0814

a numeric vector containing the growth of industry-specific employment in Freiburg 2008-2014, percentage

e_Germany2008

a numeric vector with industry-specific employment in Germany 2008

e_Germany2014

a numeric vector with industry-specific employment in Germany 2014

e_g_Germany_0814

a numeric vector containing the growth of industry-specific employment in Germany 2008-2014, percentage

color

a factor containg colors (blue, brown, ...)

Source

Statistische Aemter des Bundes und der Laender: Regionaldatenbank Deutschland, Tab. 254-74-4, own calculations

Examples

data(Freiburg)
# Loads the data
growth(Freiburg$e_Freiburg2008, Freiburg$e_Freiburg2014, growth.type = "rate")
# Industry-specific growth rates for Freiburg 2008 to 2014

Gross Domestic Product (GDP) per capita for German counties 1992-2014

Description

The dataset contains the Gross Domestic Product (GDP) absolute and per capita (in EUR, at current prices) for the 402 German counties (Landkreise) from 1992 to 2014.

Usage

data("G.counties.gdp")

Format

A data frame with 402 observations on the following 68 variables.

region_code_EU

a factor containing der EU regional code

region_code

a factor containing the German regional code

gdp1992

a numeric vector containing the GDP for German counties (Landkreise) for 1992

gdp1994

a numeric vector containing the GDP for German counties (Landkreise) for 1994

gdp1995

a numeric vector containing the GDP for German counties (Landkreise) for 1995

gdp1996

a numeric vector containing the GDP for German counties (Landkreise) for 1996

gdp1997

a numeric vector containing the GDP for German counties (Landkreise) for 1997

gdp1998

a numeric vector containing the GDP for German counties (Landkreise) for 1998

gdp1999

a numeric vector containing the GDP for German counties (Landkreise) for 1999

gdp2000

a numeric vector containing the GDP for German counties (Landkreise) for 2000

gdp2001

a numeric vector containing the GDP for German counties (Landkreise) for 2001

gdp2002

a numeric vector containing the GDP for German counties (Landkreise) for 2002

gdp2003

a numeric vector containing the GDP for German counties (Landkreise) for 2003

gdp2004

a numeric vector containing the GDP for German counties (Landkreise) for 2004

gdp2005

a numeric vector containing the GDP for German counties (Landkreise) for 2005

gdp2006

a numeric vector containing the GDP for German counties (Landkreise) for 2006

gdp2007

a numeric vector containing the GDP for German counties (Landkreise) for 2007

gdp2008

a numeric vector containing the GDP for German counties (Landkreise) for 2008

gdp2009

a numeric vector containing the GDP for German counties (Landkreise) for 2009

gdp2010

a numeric vector containing the GDP for German counties (Landkreise) for 2010

gdp2011

a numeric vector containing the GDP for German counties (Landkreise) for 2011

gdp2012

a numeric vector containing the GDP for German counties (Landkreise) for 2012

gdp2013

a numeric vector containing the GDP for German counties (Landkreise) for 2013

gdp2014

a numeric vector containing the GDP for German counties (Landkreise) for 2014

pop1992

a numeric vector containing the population for German counties (Landkreise) for 1992

pop1994

a numeric vector containing the population for German counties (Landkreise) for 1994

pop1995

a numeric vector containing the population for German counties (Landkreise) for 1995

pop1996

a numeric vector containing the population for German counties (Landkreise) for 1996

pop1997

a numeric vector containing the population for German counties (Landkreise) for 1997

pop1998

a numeric vector containing the population for German counties (Landkreise) for 1998

pop1999

a numeric vector containing the population for German counties (Landkreise) for 1999

pop2000

a numeric vector containing the population for German counties (Landkreise) for 2000

pop2001

a numeric vector containing the population for German counties (Landkreise) for 2001

pop2002

a numeric vector containing the population for German counties (Landkreise) for 2002

pop2003

a numeric vector containing the population for German counties (Landkreise) for 2003

pop2004

a numeric vector containing the population for German counties (Landkreise) for 2004

pop2005

a numeric vector containing the population for German counties (Landkreise) for 2005

pop2006

a numeric vector containing the population for German counties (Landkreise) for 2006

pop2007

a numeric vector containing the population for German counties (Landkreise) for 2007

pop2008

a numeric vector containing the population for German counties (Landkreise) for 2008

pop2009

a numeric vector containing the population for German counties (Landkreise) for 2009

pop2010

a numeric vector containing the population for German counties (Landkreise) for 2010

pop2011

a numeric vector containing the population for German counties (Landkreise) for 2011

pop2012

a numeric vector containing the population for German counties (Landkreise) for 2012

pop2013

a numeric vector containing the population for German counties (Landkreise) for 2013

pop2014

a numeric vector containing the population for German counties (Landkreise) for 2014

gdppc1992

a numeric vector containing the GDP per capita for German counties (Landkreise) for 1992

gdppc1994

a numeric vector containing the GDP per capita for German counties (Landkreise) for 1994

gdppc1995

a numeric vector containing the GDP per capita for German counties (Landkreise) for 1995

gdppc1996

a numeric vector containing the GDP per capita for German counties (Landkreise) for 1996

gdppc1997

a numeric vector containing the GDP per capita for German counties (Landkreise) for 1997

gdppc1998

a numeric vector containing the GDP per capita for German counties (Landkreise) for 1998

gdppc1999

a numeric vector containing the GDP per capita for German counties (Landkreise) for 1999

gdppc2000

a numeric vector containing the GDP per capita for German counties (Landkreise) for 2000

gdppc2001

a numeric vector containing the GDP per capita for German counties (Landkreise) for 2001

gdppc2002

a numeric vector containing the GDP per capita for German counties (Landkreise) for 2002

gdppc2003

a numeric vector containing the GDP per capita for German counties (Landkreise) for 2003

gdppc2004

a numeric vector containing the GDP per capita for German counties (Landkreise) for 2004

gdppc2005

a numeric vector containing the GDP per capita for German counties (Landkreise) for 2005

gdppc2006

a numeric vector containing the GDP per capita for German counties (Landkreise) for 2006

gdppc2007

a numeric vector containing the GDP per capita for German counties (Landkreise) for 2007

gdppc2008

a numeric vector containing the GDP per capita for German counties (Landkreise) for 2008

gdppc2009

a numeric vector containing the GDP per capita for German counties (Landkreise) for 2009

gdppc2010

a numeric vector containing the GDP per capita for German counties (Landkreise) for 2010

gdppc2011

a numeric vector containing the GDP per capita for German counties (Landkreise) for 2011

gdppc2012

a numeric vector containing the GDP per capita for German counties (Landkreise) for 2012

gdppc2013

a numeric vector containing the GDP per capita for German counties (Landkreise) for 2013

gdppc2014

a numeric vector containing the GDP per capita for German counties (Landkreise) for 2014

regional

Region West or East

Details

For the years 1992 to 1999, the GDP data is incomplete.

Source

Arbeitskreis "Volkswirtschaftliche Gesamtrechnungen der Laender" im Auftrag der Statistischen Aemter der 16 Bundeslaender, des Statistischen Bundesamtes und des Buergeramtes, Statistik und Wahlen, Frankfurt a. M. (2016): “Bruttoinlandsprodukt, Bruttowertschoepfung in den kreisfreien Staedten und Landkreisen der Bundesrepublik Deutschland 1992 und 1994 bis 2014”.

References

Arbeitskreis "Volkswirtschaftliche Gesamtrechnungen der Laender" im Auftrag der Statistischen Aemter der 16 Bundeslaender, des Statistischen Bundesamtes und des Buergeramtes, Statistik und Wahlen, Frankfurt a. M. (2016): “Bruttoinlandsprodukt, Bruttowertschoepfung in den kreisfreien Staedten und Landkreisen der Bundesrepublik Deutschland 1992 und 1994 bis 2014”.

Examples

# Regional disparities / sigma convergence in Germany
data(G.counties.gdp)
# GDP per capita for German counties (Landkreise)
cvs <- apply (G.counties.gdp[54:68], MARGIN = 2, FUN = cv)
# Calculating cv for the years 2000-2014
years <- 2000:2014
plot(years, cvs, "l", ylim=c(0.3,0.6), xlab = "year", 
ylab = "CV of GDP per capita")
# Plot cv over time

Employment data for German regions 2008-2014

Description

The dataset contains the industry-specific employment in the German region ("Bundeslaender") for the years 2008 to 2014.

Usage

data("G.regions.emp")

Format

A data frame with 1428 observations on the following 4 variables.

industry

a factor containing the industry (in German language, e.g. "Baugewerbe" = construction, "Handel, Gastgewerbe, Verkehr (G-I)" = retail, hospitality industry and transport industry)

region

a factor containing the names of the German regions (Bundeslaender)

year

a numeric vector containing the related year

emp

a numeric vector containing the related number of employees

Source

Statistische Aemter des Bundes und der Laender, Regionaldatenbank (2017): Sozialversicherungspflichtig Beschaeftigte: Beschaeftigte am Arbeitsort nach Geschlecht, Nationalitaet und Wirtschaftszweigen (Beschaeftigungsstatistik der Bundesagentur fuer Arbeit) - Stichtag 30.06. - regionale Ebenen(Tab. 254-74-4-B).

References

Statistische Aemter des Bundes und der Laender, Regionaldatenbank (2017): Sozialversicherungspflichtig Beschaeftigte: Beschaeftigte am Arbeitsort nach Geschlecht, Nationalitaet und Wirtschaftszweigen (Beschaeftigungsstatistik der Bundesagentur fuer Arbeit) - Stichtag 30.06. - regionale Ebenen(Tab. 254-74-4-B).

Examples

data(G.regions.emp)
# Concentration of construction industry in Germany
# based on 16 German regions (Bundeslaender) for the year 2008
construction2008 <- G.regions.emp[(G.regions.emp$industry == "Baugewerbe (F)" | 
G.regions.emp$industry == "Insgesamt") & G.regions.emp$year == "2008",]
# only data for construction industry (Baugewerbe) and all-over (Insgesamt)
# for the 16 German regions in the year 2008
construction2008 <- construction2008[construction2008$region != "Insgesamt",]
# delete all-over data for all industries
gini.conc(construction2008[construction2008$industry=="Baugewerbe (F)",]$emp, 
construction2008[construction2008$industry=="Insgesamt",]$emp)

# Concentration of financial industry in Germany 2008 vs. 2014
# based on 16 German regions (Bundeslaender) for 2008 and 2014
finance2008 <- G.regions.emp[(G.regions.emp$industry == 
"Erbringung von Finanz- und Vers.leistungen (K)" | 
G.regions.emp$industry == "Insgesamt") & G.regions.emp$year == "2008",]
finance2008 <- finance2008[finance2008$region != "Insgesamt",]
# delete all-over data for all industries
gini.conc(finance2008[finance2008$industry == 
"Erbringung von Finanz- und Vers.leistungen (K)",]$emp, 
finance2008[finance2008$industry=="Insgesamt",]$emp)
finance2014 <- G.regions.emp[(G.regions.emp$industry == 
"Erbringung von Finanz- und Vers.leistungen (K)" | G.regions.emp$industry ==
"Insgesamt") & G.regions.emp$year == "2014",]
finance2014 <- finance2014[finance2014$region != "Insgesamt",]
# delete all-over data for all industries
gini.conc(finance2014[finance2014$industry == 
"Erbringung von Finanz- und Vers.leistungen (K)",]$emp, 
finance2014[finance2014$industry=="Insgesamt",]$emp)

Firms and employment data for German regions 2015

Description

The dataset contains the industry-specific firm stock and employment in the German regions ("Bundeslaender") for 2015.

Usage

data("G.regions.industries")

Format

A data frame with 272 observations on the following 9 variables.

year

a numeric vector containing the related year

region

a factor containing the names of the German regions (Bundeslaender)

region_code

a factor containing the codes of the German regions (Bundeslaender)

ind_code

a factor containing the codes of the industries (WZ2008)

ind_name

a factor containing the names of the industries (WZ2008)

firms

a numeric vector containing the related number of firms

emp_all

a numeric vector containing the related number of employees (incl. self-employed)

pop

a numeric vector containing the related population

area_sqkm

a numeric vector containing the related region size (in sqkm)

Source

Compiled from:

Statistisches Bundesamt (2019): Tab. 11111-0001 - Gebietsflaeche: Bundeslaender, Stichtag.

Statistisches Bundesamt (2019): Tab. 12411-0010 - Bevoelkerung: Bundeslaender, Stichtag.

Statistisches Bundesamt (2019): Tab. 13311-0002 - Erwerbstaetige, Arbeitnehmer, Selbstaendige und mithelfende Familienangehoerige (im Inland): Bundeslaender, Jahre, Wirtschaftszweige (Arbeitskreis "Erwerbstaetigenrechnung des Bundes und der Laender").

Statistisches Bundesamt (2019): Tab. 52111-0004 - Betriebe (Unternehmensregister-System): Bundeslaender, Jahre, Wirtschaftszweige (Abschnitte), Beschaeftigtengroessenklassen.

Examples

data (G.regions.industries)

lqs <- locq2(e_ij = G.regions.industries$emp_all, 
G.regions.industries$ind_code, G.regions.industries$region_code, 
LQ.output = "df")
# output as data frame

lqs_sort <- lqs[order(lqs$LQ, decreasing = TRUE),]
# Sort decreasing by size of LQ

lqs_sort[1:5,]

Commercial area prognosis

Description

This function contains the basic GIFPRO model for commercial area prognosis (GIFPRO = Gewerbe- und Industrieflaechenprognose)

Usage

gifpro(e_ij, a_i, sq_ij, rq_ij, ru_ij = NULL, ai_ij, time.base, tinterval = 1, 
industry.names = NULL, output = "short")

Arguments

e_ij

a numeric vector with ii values containing the current employment in ii industries in region jj

a_i

a numeric vector with ii values containing the share of employees in industry ii which is located in commercial areas

sq_ij

a numeric vector with ii values containing the annual quote of resettled employees (Neuansiedlungsquote in German) in industry ii, in percent

rq_ij

a numeric vector with ii values containing the annual quote of relocated employees (Verlagerungsquote in German) in industry ii, in percent

ru_ij

a numeric vector with ii values containing the annual quote of employees in industry ii which is located in reused commercial area (Wiedernutzungsquote in German), in percent (default: ru_ij = NULL, which represents a quote of 0 percent, meaning that no commercial area can be reused)

ai_ij

a numeric vector with ii values containing the areal index (Flaechenkennziffer in German), representing the area requirement (e.g. in sqm) per employee in industry ii

time.base

a single value representing the start time of the prognose (typically current year + 1)

tinterval

a single value representing the forecast horizon (length of time into the future for which the commercial area prognosis is done), in time units (e.g. tinterval = 10 = 10 years)

industry.names

a vector containing the industry names (e.g. from the relevant statistical classification of economic activities)

output

Type of output: output = "short" (default) shows the final number of relevant employment and commercial area requirement. If output = "full", employment and commercial area are displayed for each time unit (year)

Details

In municipal land use planning (mostly in Germany), the future need of local commercial area (which is a type of land use, defined in official land-use plans) is mostly forecasted by models founded on the GIFPRO model (Gewerbe- und Industrieflaechenbedarfsprognose, prognosis of future demand of commercial area). GIFPRO is a demand-side model, which means predicting the demand of commercial area based on a prognosis of future employment in different industries (Bonny/Kahnert 2005). The key parameters of the model are the (assumed) shares of employees located in commercial areas (aia_i), the (assumed) quotas of resettlement (sqijsq_{ij}), relocation (rqijrq_{ij}) and (sometimes) reuse (ruijru_{ij}) as well as the (assumed) area requirement per employee (aiijai_{ij}). Outgoing from current employment in ii industries in region jj, eije_{ij}, the future employment is predicted based on the quotas mentioned above and, finally, multiplied by the industry-specific (and maybe region-specific) areal index. The GIFPRO model has been modified and extended several times, especially with respect to industry- and region-specific employment growth, quotas and areal indices (Deutsches Institut fuer Urbanistik 2010, Vallee et al. 2012).

Value

A list containing the following objects:

components

Matrices containing the single components (resettlement, relocation, reuse, relevant employment)

results

Matrices containing the final results per year and all over

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Bonny, H.-W./Kahnert, R. (2005): “Zur Ermittlung des Gewerbeflaechenbedarfs: Ein Vergleich zwischen einer Monitoring gestuetzten Prognose und einer analytischen Bestimmung”. In: Raumforschung und Raumordnung, 63, 3, p. 232-240.

Deutsches Institut fuer Urbanistik (ed.) (2010): “Stadtentwicklungskonzept Gewerbe fuer die Landeshauptstadt Potsdam”. Berlin. https://www.potsdam.de/sites/default/files/documents/STEK_Gewerbe_Langfassung_2010.pdf (accessed October 13, 2017).

Vallee, D./Witte, A./Brandt, T./Bischof, T. (2012): “Bedarfsberechnung fuer die Darstellung von Allgemeinen Siedlungsbereichen (ASB) und Gewerbe- und Industrieansiedlungsbereichen (GIB) in Regionalplaenen”. Im Auftrag der Staatskanzlei des Landes Nordrhein-Westfalen. Abschlussbericht Oktober 2012. Aachen.

See Also

gifpro.tbs, portfolio, shift, shiftd, shifti

Examples

# Data for the city Kempten (2012):
emp2012 <- c(7228, 12452, 11589)
sharesCA <- c(100, 40, 10)
rsquote <- c(0.3, 0.3, 0.3)
rlquote <- c(0.7, 0.7, 0.7)
arealindex <- c(148, 148, 148)
industries <- c("Manufacturing", "Wholesale and retail trade, Transportation 
and storage, Information and communication", "Other services")

gifpro (e_ij = emp2012, a_i = sharesCA,  sq_ij = rsquote,
rq_ij = rlquote, ai_ij = arealindex, time.base = 2012, 
tinterval = 13, industry.names = industries, output = "short")
# short output

gifpro (e_ij = emp2012, a_i = sharesCA,  sq_ij = rsquote,
rq_ij = rlquote, ai_ij = arealindex, time.base = 2012, 
tinterval = 13, industry.names = industries, output = "full")
# full output

gifpro_results <- gifpro (e_ij = emp2012, a_i = sharesCA,  sq_ij = rsquote,
rq_ij = rlquote, ai_ij = arealindex, time.base = 2012, 
tinterval = 13, industry.names = industries, output = "short")
# saving results as gifpro object

gifpro_results$components
# single components

gifpro_results$results
# results (as shown in full output)

Trend-based and location-specific commercial area prognosis

Description

This function contains the TBS-GIFPRO model for commercial area prognosis (TBS-GIFPRO = Trendbasierte und standortspezifische Gewerbe- und Industrieflaechenprognose; trend-based and location-specific commercial area prognosis)

Usage

gifpro.tbs(e_ij, a_i, sq_ij, rq_ij, ru_ij = NULL, ai_ij, 
time.base, tinterval = 1, prog.func = rep("lin", nrow(e_ij)), 
prog.plot = TRUE, plot.single = FALSE,
multiplot.col = NULL, multiplot.row = NULL,
industry.names = NULL, emp.only = FALSE, output = "short")

Arguments

e_ij

a numeric vector with ii values containing the current employment in ii industries in region jj

a_i

a numeric vector with ii values containing the share of employees in industry ii which is located in commercial areas

sq_ij

a numeric vector with ii values containing the annual quote of resettled employees (Neuansiedlungsquote in German) in industry ii, in percent

rq_ij

a numeric vector with ii values containing the annual quote of relocated employees (Verlagerungsquote in German) in industry ii, in percent

ru_ij

a numeric vector with ii values containing the annual quote of employees in industry ii which is located in reused commercial area (Wiedernutzungsquote in German), in percent (default: ru_ij = NULL, which represents a quote of 0 percent, meaning that no commercial area can be reused)

ai_ij

a numeric vector with ii values containing the areal index (Flaechenkennziffer in German), representing the area requirement (e.g. in sqm) per employee in industry ii

time.base

a single value representing the start time of the prognose (typically current year + 1)

tinterval

a single value representing the forecast horizon (length of time into the future for which the commercial area prognosis is done), in time units (e.g. tinterval = 10 = 10 years)

prog.func

a vector containing the estimation function types for employment prognosis ("lin" for linear, "pow" for power, "exp" for exponential and "logi" for logistic function); must have the same length as e_ij and industry.names, respectively

prog.plot

Logical argument that indicates if the employment prognoses have to be plotted

plot.single

If prog.plot = TRUE: Logical argument that indicates if the plots are stored as single graphic devices or integrated in one plot

multiplot.col

No. of columns in plot

multiplot.row

No. of rows in plot

industry.names

a vector containing the industry names (e.g. from the relevant statistical classification of economic activities)

emp.only

Logical argument that indicates if the analysis only contains employment prognosis

output

Type of output: output = "short" (default) shows the final number of relevant employment and commercial area requirement. If output = "full", employment and commercial area are displayed for each time unit (year)

Details

In municipal land use planning (mostly in Germany), the future need of local commercial area (which is a type of land use, defined in official land-use plans) is mostly forecasted by models founded on the GIFPRO model (Gewerbe- und Industrieflaechenbedarfsprognose, prognosis of future demand of commercial area). GIFPRO is a demand-side model, which means predicting the demand of commercial area based on a prognosis of future employment in different industries (Bonny/Kahnert 2005). The key parameters of the model are the (assumed) shares of employees located in commercial areas (aia_i), the (assumed) quotas of resettlement (sqijsq_{ij}), relocation (rqijrq_{ij}) and (sometimes) reuse (ruijru_{ij}) as well as the (assumed) area requirement per employee (aiijai_{ij}). Outgoing from current employment in ii industries in region jj, eije_{ij}, the future employment is predicted based on the quotas mentioned above and, finally, multiplied by the industry-specific (and maybe region-specific) areal index. The GIFPRO model has been modified and extended several times, especially with respect to industry- and region-specific employment growth, quotas and areal indices (Deutsches Institut fuer Urbanistik 2010, Vallee et al. 2012).

This function contains the TBS-GIFPRO model for commercial area prognosis (TBS-GIFPRO = Trendbasierte und standortspezifische Gewerbe- und Industrieflaechenprognose; trend-based and location-specific commercial area prognosis) (Deutsches Institut fuer Urbanistik 2010).

Value

A list containing the following objects:

components

List with matrices containing the single components (resettlement, relocation, reuse, relevant employment)

results

List with matrices containing the final results per year and all over as well as the industry-specific forecast data

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Bonny, H.-W./Kahnert, R. (2005): “Zur Ermittlung des Gewerbeflaechenbedarfs: Ein Vergleich zwischen einer Monitoring gestuetzten Prognose und einer analytischen Bestimmung”. In: Raumforschung und Raumordnung, 63, 3, p. 232-240.

Deutsches Institut fuer Urbanistik (ed.) (2010): “Stadtentwicklungskonzept Gewerbe fuer die Landeshauptstadt Potsdam”. Berlin. https://www.potsdam.de/sites/default/files/documents/STEK_Gewerbe_Langfassung_2010.pdf (accessed October 13, 2017).

Vallee, D./Witte, A./Brandt, T./Bischof, T. (2012): “Bedarfsberechnung fuer die Darstellung von Allgemeinen Siedlungsbereichen (ASB) und Gewerbe- und Industrieansiedlungsbereichen (GIB) in Regionalplaenen”. Im Auftrag der Staatskanzlei des Landes Nordrhein-Westfalen. Abschlussbericht Oktober 2012.

See Also

gifpro, portfolio, shift, shiftd, shifti

Examples

# Data for Goettingen:
data(Goettingen)

anteileGOE <- rep(100,15)
nvquote <- rep (0.3, 15)
vlquote <- rep (0.7, 15)

gifpro.tbs (e_ij = Goettingen[2:16,3:12], 
a_i = anteileGOE, sq_ij = nvquote,
rq_ij = vlquote, tinterval = 12, prog.func = 
rep("lin", nrow(Goettingen[2:16,3:12])),
ai_ij = 150, time.base = 2008, output = "full",
industry.names = Goettingen$WZ2008_Code[2:16],
prog.plot = TRUE, plot.single = FALSE)

Gini coefficient

Description

Calculating the Gini coefficient of inequality (or concentration), standardized and non-standardized, and optionally plotting the Lorenz curve

Usage

gini(x, coefnorm = FALSE, weighting = NULL, na.rm = TRUE, lc = FALSE, 
lcx = "% of objects", lcy = "% of regarded variable", 
lctitle = "Lorenz curve", le.col = "blue", lc.col = "black",
lsize = 1, ltype = "solid",
bg.col = "gray95", bgrid = TRUE, bgrid.col = "white", 
bgrid.size = 2, bgrid.type = "solid",
lcg = FALSE, lcgn = FALSE, lcg.caption = NULL, 
lcg.lab.x = 0, lcg.lab.y = 1, add.lc = FALSE)

Arguments

x

A numeric vector (e.g. dataset of household income, sales turnover or supply)

coefnorm

logical argument that indicates if the function output is the non-standardized or the standardized Gini coefficient (default: coefnorm = FALSE, that means the non-standardized Gini coefficient is returned)

weighting

A numeric vector containing the weighting data (e.g. size of income classes when calculating a Gini coefficient for aggregated income data)

na.rm

logical argument that indicates whether NA values should be excluded before computing results

lc

logical argument that indicates if the Lorenz curve is plotted additionally (default: lc = FALSE, so no Lorenz curve is displayed)

lcx

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), lcx defines the x axis label

lcy

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), lcy defines the y axis label

lctitle

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), lctitle defines the overall title of the Lorenz curve plot

le.col

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), le.col defines the color of the diagonale (line of equality)

lc.col

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), lc.col defines the color of the Lorenz curve

lsize

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), lsize defines the size of the lines (default: 1)

ltype

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), ltype defines the type of the lines (default: "solid")

bg.col

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), bg.col defines the background color of the plot (default: "gray95")

bgrid

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), the logical argument bgrid defines if a grid is shown in the plot

bgrid.col

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve) and bgrid = TRUE (background grid), bgrid.col defines the color of the background grid (default: "white")

bgrid.size

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve) and bgrid = TRUE (background grid), bgrid.size defines the size of the background grid (default: 2)

bgrid.type

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve) and bgrid = TRUE (background grid), bgrid.type defines the type of lines of the background grid (default: "solid")

lcg

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), the logical argument lcg defines if the non-standardized Gini coefficient is displayed in the Lorenz curve plot

lcgn

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), the logical argument lcgn defines if the standardized Gini coefficient is displayed in the Lorenz curve plot

lcg.caption

if lcg = TRUE (displaying the Gini coefficient in the plot), lcg.caption specifies the caption above the coefficients

lcg.lab.x

if lcg = TRUE (displaying the Gini coefficient in the plot), lcg.lab.x specifies the x coordinate of the label

lcg.lab.y

if lcg = TRUE (displaying the Gini coefficient in the plot), lcg.lab.y specifies the y coordinate of the label

add.lc

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), add.lc specifies if a new Lorenz curve is plotted (add.lc = "FALSE") or the plot is added to an existing Lorenz curve plot (add.lc = "TRUE")

Details

The Gini coefficient (Gini 1912) is a popular measure of statistical dispersion, especially used for analyzing inequality or concentration. The Lorenz curve (Lorenz 1905), though developed independently, can be regarded as a graphical representation of the degree of inequality/concentration calculated by the Gini coefficient (GG) and can also be used for additional interpretations of it. In an economic-geographical context, these methods are frequently used to analyse the concentration/inequality of income or wealth within countries (Aoyama et al. 2011). Other areas of application are analyzing regional disparities (Lessmann 2005, Nakamura 2008) and concentration in markets (sales turnover of competing firms) which makes Gini and Lorenz part of economic statistics in general (Doersam 2004, Roberts 2014).

The Gini coefficient (GG) varies between 0 (no inequality/concentration) and 1 (complete inequality/concentration). The Lorenz curve displays the deviations of the empirical distribution from a perfectly equal distribution as the difference between two graphs (the distribution curve and a diagonal line of perfect equality). This function calculates GG and plots the Lorenz curve optionally. As there are several ways to calculate the Gini coefficient, this function uses the formula given in Doersam (2004). Because the maximum of GG is not equal to 1, also a standardized coefficient (GG*) with a maximum equal to 1 can be calculated alternatively. If a Gini coefficient for aggregated data (e.g. income classes with averaged incomes) or the Gini coefficient has to be weighted, use a weighting vector (e.g. size of the income classes).

Value

A single numeric value of the Gini coefficient (0<G<10 < G < 1) or the standardized Gini coefficient (0<G<10 < G* < 1) and, optionally, a plot of the Lorenz curve.

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Aoyama, Y./Murphy, J. T./Hanson, S. (2011): “Key Concepts in Economic Geography”. London : SAGE.

Bahrenberg, G./Giese, E./Mevenkamp, N./Nipper, J. (2010): “Statistische Methoden in der Geographie. Band 1: Univariate und bivariate Statistik”. Stuttgart: Borntraeger.

Cerlani, L./Verme, P. (2012): “The origins of the Gini index: extracts from Variabilita e Mutabilita (1912) by Corrado Gini”. In: The Journal of Economic Inequality, 10, 3, p. 421-443.

Doersam, P. (2004): “Wirtschaftsstatistik anschaulich dargestellt”. Heidenau : PD-Verlag.

Gini, C. (1912): “Variabilita e Mutabilita”. Contributo allo Studio delle Distribuzioni e delle Relazioni Statistiche. Bologna : Cuppini.

Lessmann, C. (2005): “Regionale Disparitaeten in Deutschland und ausgesuchten OECD-Staaten im Vergleich”. ifo Dresden berichtet, 3/2005. https://www.ifo.de/DocDL/ifodb_2005_3_25-33.pdf.

Lorenz, M. O. (1905): “Methods of Measuring the Concentration of Wealth”. In: Publications of the American Statistical Association, 9, 70, p. 209-219.

Nakamura, R. (2008): “Agglomeration Effects on Regional Economic Disparities: A Comparison between the UK and Japan”. In: Urban Studies, 45, 9, p. 1947-1971.

Roberts, T. (2014): “When Bigger Is Better: A Critique of the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index's Use to Evaluate Mergers in Network Industries”. In: Pace Law Review, 34, 2, p. 894-946.

See Also

cv, gini.conc, gini.spec, herf, hoover

Examples

# Market concentration (example from Doersam 2004):
sales <- c(20,50,20,10)
# sales turnover of four car manufacturing companies
gini (sales, lc = TRUE, lcx = "percentage of companies", lcy = "percentrage of sales", 
lctitle = "Lorenz curve of sales", lcg = TRUE, lcgn = TRUE)
# returs the non-standardized Gini coefficient (0.3) and 
# plots the Lorenz curve with user-defined title and labels 
gini (sales, coefnorm = TRUE)
# returns the standardized Gini coefficient (0.4)

# Income classes (example from Doersam 2004):
income <- c(500, 1500, 2500, 4000, 7500, 15000)
# average income of 6 income classes
sizeofclass <- c(1000, 1200, 1600, 400, 200, 600)
# size of income classes
gini (income, weighting = sizeofclass)
# returns the non-standardized Gini coefficient (0.5278)

# Market concentration in automotive industry
data(Automotive)
gini(Automotive$Turnover2008, lsize=1, lc=TRUE, le.col = "black", 
lc.col = "orange", lcx = "Shares of companies", lcy = "Shares of turnover / cars", 
lctitle = "Automotive industry: market concentration", 
lcg = TRUE, lcgn = TRUE, lcg.caption = "Turnover 2008:", lcg.lab.x = 0, lcg.lab.y = 1)
# Gini coefficient and Lorenz curve for turnover 2008
gini(Automotive$Turnover2013, lsize=1, lc = TRUE, add.lc = TRUE, lc.col = "red", 
lcg = TRUE, lcgn = TRUE, lcg.caption = "Turnover 2013:", lcg.lab.x = 0, lcg.lab.y = 0.85)
# Adding Gini coefficient and Lorenz curve for turnover 2013
gini(Automotive$Quantity2014_car, lsize=1, lc = TRUE, add.lc = TRUE, lc.col = "blue", 
lcg = TRUE, lcgn = TRUE, lcg.caption = "Cars 2014:", lcg.lab.x = 0, lcg.lab.y = 0.7)
# Adding Gini coefficient and Lorenz curve for cars 2014

# Regional disparities in Germany:
gdp <- c(460.69, 549.19, 124.16, 65.29, 31.59, 109.27, 263.44, 39.87, 258.53, 
645.59, 131.95, 35.03, 112.66, 56.22, 85.61, 56.81)
# GDP of german regions (Bundeslaender) 2015 (in billion EUR)
gini(gdp)
# returs the non-standardized Gini coefficient (0.5009)

Gini coefficient of spatial industry concentration

Description

Calculating the Gini coefficient of spatial industry concentration based on regional industry data (normally employment data)

Usage

gini.conc(e_ij, e_j, lc = FALSE, lcx = "% of objects", 
lcy = "% of regarded variable", lctitle = "Lorenz curve", 
le.col = "blue", lc.col = "black", lsize = 1, ltype = "solid",
bg.col = "gray95", bgrid = TRUE, bgrid.col = "white", 
bgrid.size = 2, bgrid.type = "solid", lcg = FALSE, lcgn = FALSE, 
lcg.caption = NULL, lcg.lab.x = 0, lcg.lab.y = 1, 
add.lc = FALSE, plot.lc = TRUE)

Arguments

e_ij

a numeric vector with the employment of the industry ii in region jj

e_j

a numeric vector with the employment in region jj

lc

logical argument that indicates if the Lorenz curve is plotted additionally (default: lc = FALSE, so no Lorenz curve is displayed)

lcx

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), lcx defines the x axis label

lcy

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), lcy defines the y axis label

lctitle

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), lctitle defines the overall title of the Lorenz curve plot

le.col

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), le.col defines the color of the diagonale (line of equality)

lc.col

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), lc.col defines the color of the Lorenz curve

lsize

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), lsize defines the size of the lines (default: 1)

ltype

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), ltype defines the type of the lines (default: "solid")

bg.col

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), bg.col defines the background color of the plot (default: "gray95")

bgrid

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), the logical argument bgrid defines if a grid is shown in the plot

bgrid.col

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve) and bgrid = TRUE (background grid), bgrid.col defines the color of the background grid (default: "white")

bgrid.size

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve) and bgrid = TRUE (background grid), bgrid.size defines the size of the background grid (default: 2)

bgrid.type

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve) and bgrid = TRUE (background grid), bgrid.type defines the type of lines of the background grid (default: "solid")

lcg

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), the logical argument lcg defines if the non-standardized Gini coefficient is displayed in the Lorenz curve plot

lcgn

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), the logical argument lcgn defines if the standardized Gini coefficient is displayed in the Lorenz curve plot

lcg.caption

if lcg = TRUE (displaying the Gini coefficient in the plot), lcg.caption specifies the caption above the coefficients

lcg.lab.x

if lcg = TRUE (displaying the Gini coefficient in the plot), lcg.lab.x specifies the x coordinate of the label

lcg.lab.y

if lcg = TRUE (displaying the Gini coefficient in the plot), lcg.lab.y specifies the y coordinate of the label

add.lc

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), add.lc specifies if a new Lorenz curve is plotted (add.lc = "FALSE") or the plot is added to an existing Lorenz curve plot (add.lc = "TRUE")

plot.lc

logical argument that indicates if the Lorenz curve itself is plotted (if plot.lc = FALSE, only the line of equality is plotted))

Details

The Gini coefficient of spatial industry concentration (GiG_{i}) is a special spatial modification of the Gini coefficient of inequality (see the function gini()). It represents the rate of spatial concentration of the industry ii referring to jj regions (e.g. cities, counties, states). The coefficient GiG_{i} varies between 0 (perfect distribution, respectively no concentration) and 1 (complete concentration in one region). Optionally a Lorenz curve is plotted (if lc = TRUE).

Value

A single numeric value (0<Gi<10 < G_{i} < 1)

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Farhauer, O./Kroell, A. (2013): “Standorttheorien: Regional- und Stadtoekonomik in Theorie und Praxis”. Wiesbaden : Springer.

Nakamura, R./Morrison Paul, C. J. (2009): “Measuring agglomeration”. In: Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (eds.): Handbook of Regional Growth and Development Theories. Cheltenham: Elgar. p. 305-328.

See Also

gini, gini.spec

Examples

# Example from Farhauer/Kroell (2013):
E_ij <- c(500,500,1000,7000,1000)
# employment of the industry in five regions
E_j <- c(20000,15000,20000,40000,5000)
# employment in the five regions
gini.conc (E_ij, E_j)
# Returns the Gini coefficient of industry concentration (0.4068966)

data(G.regions.emp)
# Concentration of construction industry in Germany
# based on 16 German regions (Bundeslaender) for the year 2008
construction2008 <- G.regions.emp[(G.regions.emp$industry == "Baugewerbe (F)" | 
G.regions.emp$industry == "Insgesamt") & G.regions.emp$year == "2008",]
# only data for construction industry (Baugewerbe) and all-over (Insgesamt)
# for the 16 German regions in the year 2008
construction2008 <- construction2008[construction2008$region != "Insgesamt",]
# delete all-over data for all industries
gini.conc(construction2008[construction2008$industry=="Baugewerbe (F)",]$emp, 
construction2008[construction2008$industry=="Insgesamt",]$emp)

# Concentration of financial industry in Germany 2008 vs. 2014
# based on 16 German regions (Bundeslaender) for 2008 and 2014
finance2008 <- G.regions.emp[(G.regions.emp$industry == 
"Erbringung von Finanz- und Vers.leistungen (K)" | 
G.regions.emp$industry == "Insgesamt") & G.regions.emp$year == "2008",]
finance2008 <- finance2008[finance2008$region != "Insgesamt",]
# delete all-over data for all industries
gini.conc(finance2008[finance2008$industry == 
"Erbringung von Finanz- und Vers.leistungen (K)",]$emp, 
finance2008[finance2008$industry=="Insgesamt",]$emp)
finance2014 <- G.regions.emp[(G.regions.emp$industry == 
"Erbringung von Finanz- und Vers.leistungen (K)" | G.regions.emp$industry ==
"Insgesamt") & G.regions.emp$year == "2014",]
finance2014 <- finance2014[finance2014$region != "Insgesamt",]
# delete all-over data for all industries
gini.conc(finance2014[finance2014$industry == 
"Erbringung von Finanz- und Vers.leistungen (K)",]$emp, 
finance2014[finance2014$industry=="Insgesamt",]$emp)

Gini coefficient of regional specialization

Description

Calculating the Gini coefficient of regional specialization based on regional industry data (normally employment data)

Usage

gini.spec(e_ij, e_i, lc = FALSE, lcx = "% of objects", 
lcy = "% of regarded variable", lctitle = "Lorenz curve", 
le.col = "blue", lc.col = "black", lsize = 1, ltype = "solid",
bg.col = "gray95", bgrid = TRUE, bgrid.col = "white", 
bgrid.size = 2, bgrid.type = "solid", lcg = FALSE, lcgn = FALSE, 
lcg.caption = NULL, lcg.lab.x = 0, lcg.lab.y = 1, 
add.lc = FALSE, plot.lc = TRUE)

Arguments

e_ij

a numeric vector with the employment of the industries ii in region jj

e_i

a numeric vector with the employment in the industries ii

lc

logical argument that indicates if the Lorenz curve is plotted additionally (default: lc = FALSE, so no Lorenz curve is displayed)

lcx

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), lcx defines the x axis label

lcy

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), lcy defines the y axis label

lctitle

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), lctitle defines the overall title of the Lorenz curve plot

le.col

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), le.col defines the color of the diagonale (line of equality)

lc.col

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), lc.col defines the color of the Lorenz curve

lsize

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), lsize defines the size of the lines (default: 1)

ltype

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), ltype defines the type of the lines (default: "solid")

bg.col

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), bg.col defines the background color of the plot (default: "gray95")

bgrid

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), the logical argument bgrid defines if a grid is shown in the plot

bgrid.col

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve) and bgrid = TRUE (background grid), bgrid.col defines the color of the background grid (default: "white")

bgrid.size

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve) and bgrid = TRUE (background grid), bgrid.size defines the size of the background grid (default: 2)

bgrid.type

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve) and bgrid = TRUE (background grid), bgrid.type defines the type of lines of the background grid (default: "solid")

lcg

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), the logical argument lcg defines if the non-standardized Gini coefficient is displayed in the Lorenz curve plot

lcgn

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), the logical argument lcgn defines if the standardized Gini coefficient is displayed in the Lorenz curve plot

lcg.caption

if lcg = TRUE (displaying the Gini coefficient in the plot), lcg.caption specifies the caption above the coefficients

lcg.lab.x

if lcg = TRUE (displaying the Gini coefficient in the plot), lcg.lab.x specifies the x coordinate of the label

lcg.lab.y

if lcg = TRUE (displaying the Gini coefficient in the plot), lcg.lab.y specifies the y coordinate of the label

add.lc

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), add.lc specifies if a new Lorenz curve is plotted (add.lc = "FALSE") or the plot is added to an existing Lorenz curve plot (add.lc = "TRUE")

plot.lc

logical argument that indicates if the Lorenz curve itself is plotted (if plot.lc = FALSE, only the line of equality is plotted))

Details

The Gini coefficient of regional specialization (GjG_{j}) is a special spatial modification of the Gini coefficient of inequality (see the function gini()). It represents the degree of regional specialization of the region jj referring to ii industries. The coefficient GjG_{j} varies between 0 (no specialization) and 1 (complete specialization). Optionally a Lorenz curve is plotted (if lc = TRUE).

Value

A single numeric value (0<Gj<10 < G_{j} < 1)

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Farhauer, O./Kroell, A. (2013): “Standorttheorien: Regional- und Stadtoekonomik in Theorie und Praxis”. Wiesbaden : Springer.

Nakamura, R./Morrison Paul, C. J. (2009): “Measuring agglomeration”. In: Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (eds.): Handbook of Regional Growth and Development Theories. Cheltenham: Elgar. p. 305-328.

See Also

gini, gini.conc

Examples

# Example from Farhauer/Kroell (2013):
E_ij <- c(700,600,500,10000,40000)
# employment of five industries in the region
E_i <- c(30000,15000,10000,60000,50000)
# over-all employment in the five industries
gini.spec (E_ij, E_i)
# Returns the Gini coefficient of regional specialization (0.6222222)

# Example Freiburg
data(Freiburg)
# Loads the data
E_ij <- Freiburg$e_Freiburg2014
# industry-specific employment in Freiburg 2014
E_i <- Freiburg$e_Germany2014
# industry-specific employment in Germany 2014
gini.spec (E_ij, E_i)
# Returns the Gini coefficient of regional specialization (0.2089009)

# Example Goettingen
data(Goettingen)
# Loads the data
gini.spec(Goettingen$Goettingen2017[2:16], Goettingen$BRD2017[2:16])
# Returns the Gini coefficient of regional specialization 2017 (0.359852)

Gini coefficient

Description

Calculating the Gini coefficient of inequality (or concentration), standardized and non-standardized, and optionally plotting the Lorenz curve

Usage

gini2(x, weighting = NULL, coefnorm = FALSE, na.rm = TRUE)

Arguments

x

A numeric vector (e.g. dataset of regional incomes)

weighting

A numeric vector containing the weighting data (e.g. regional population)

coefnorm

logical argument that indicates if the function output is the non-standardized or the standardized Gini coefficient (default: coefnorm = FALSE, which means the non-standardized Gini coefficient is returned)

na.rm

logical argument that indicates whether NA values should be excluded before computing results

Details

The Gini coefficient (Gini 1912) is a popular measure of statistical dispersion, especially used for analyzing inequality or concentration. In an economic-geographical context, the Gini coefficient is frequently used to analyse the concentration/inequality of income or wealth within countries (Aoyama et al. 2011). Other areas of application are analyzing regional disparities (Lessmann 2005, Nakamura 2008) and concentration in markets (sales turnover of competing firms).

The Gini coefficient (GG) varies between 0 (no inequality/concentration) and 1 (complete inequality/concentration). This function calculates GG. As there are several ways to calculate the Gini coefficient, this function uses the formula given in Doersam (2004). Because the maximum of GG is not equal to 1, also a standardized coefficient (GG*) with a maximum equal to 1 can be calculated alternatively. If a Gini coefficient for aggregated data (e.g. income classes with averaged incomes) or the Gini coefficient has to be weighted, use a weighting vector (e.g. size of the income classes).

Value

A single numeric value of the Gini coefficient (0<G<10 < G < 1) or the standardized Gini coefficient (0<G<10 < G* < 1) and, optionally, a plot of the Lorenz curve.

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Aoyama, Y./Murphy, J. T./Hanson, S. (2011): “Key Concepts in Economic Geography”. London : SAGE.

Bahrenberg, G./Giese, E./Mevenkamp, N./Nipper, J. (2010): “Statistische Methoden in der Geographie. Band 1: Univariate und bivariate Statistik”. Stuttgart: Borntraeger.

Cerlani, L./Verme, P. (2012): “The origins of the Gini index: extracts from Variabilita e Mutabilita (1912) by Corrado Gini”. In: The Journal of Economic Inequality, 10, 3, p. 421-443.

Doersam, P. (2004): “Wirtschaftsstatistik anschaulich dargestellt”. Heidenau : PD-Verlag.

Gini, C. (1912): “Variabilita e Mutabilita”. Contributo allo Studio delle Distribuzioni e delle Relazioni Statistiche. Bologna : Cuppini.

Lessmann, C. (2005): “Regionale Disparitaeten in Deutschland und ausgesuchten OECD-Staaten im Vergleich”. ifo Dresden berichtet, 3/2005. https://www.ifo.de/DocDL/ifodb_2005_3_25-33.pdf.

Lorenz, M. O. (1905): “Methods of Measuring the Concentration of Wealth”. In: Publications of the American Statistical Association, 9, 70, p. 209-219.

Nakamura, R. (2008): “Agglomeration Effects on Regional Economic Disparities: A Comparison between the UK and Japan”. In: Urban Studies, 45, 9, p. 1947-1971.

Roberts, T. (2014): “When Bigger Is Better: A Critique of the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index's Use to Evaluate Mergers in Network Industries”. In: Pace Law Review, 34, 2, p. 894-946.

See Also

cv, gini.conc, gini.spec, herf, hoover

Examples

# Market concentration (example from Doersam 2004):
sales <- c(20,50,20,10)
# sales turnover of four car manufacturing companies
gini (sales, lc = TRUE, lcx = "percentage of companies", lcy = "percentrage of sales", 
lctitle = "Lorenz curve of sales", lcg = TRUE, lcgn = TRUE)
# returs the non-standardized Gini coefficient (0.3) and 
# plots the Lorenz curve with user-defined title and labels 
gini (sales, coefnorm = TRUE)
# returns the standardized Gini coefficient (0.4)

# Income classes (example from Doersam 2004):
income <- c(500, 1500, 2500, 4000, 7500, 15000)
# average income of 6 income classes
sizeofclass <- c(1000, 1200, 1600, 400, 200, 600)
# size of income classes
gini (income, weighting = sizeofclass)
# returns the non-standardized Gini coefficient (0.5278)

# Market concentration in automotive industry
data(Automotive)
gini(Automotive$Turnover2008, lsize=1, lc=TRUE, le.col = "black", 
lc.col = "orange", lcx = "Shares of companies", lcy = "Shares of turnover / cars", 
lctitle = "Automotive industry: market concentration", 
lcg = TRUE, lcgn = TRUE, lcg.caption = "Turnover 2008:", lcg.lab.x = 0, lcg.lab.y = 1)
# Gini coefficient and Lorenz curve for turnover 2008
gini(Automotive$Turnover2013, lsize=1, lc = TRUE, add.lc = TRUE, lc.col = "red", 
lcg = TRUE, lcgn = TRUE, lcg.caption = "Turnover 2013:", lcg.lab.x = 0, lcg.lab.y = 0.85)
# Adding Gini coefficient and Lorenz curve for turnover 2013
gini(Automotive$Quantity2014_car, lsize=1, lc = TRUE, add.lc = TRUE, lc.col = "blue", 
lcg = TRUE, lcgn = TRUE, lcg.caption = "Cars 2014:", lcg.lab.x = 0, lcg.lab.y = 0.7)
# Adding Gini coefficient and Lorenz curve for cars 2014

# Regional disparities in Germany:
gdp <- c(460.69, 549.19, 124.16, 65.29, 31.59, 109.27, 263.44, 39.87, 258.53, 
645.59, 131.95, 35.03, 112.66, 56.22, 85.61, 56.81)
# GDP of german regions (Bundeslaender) 2015 (in billion EUR)
gini(gdp)
# returs the non-standardized Gini coefficient (0.5009)

Employment data for Goettingen and Germany 2008-2017

Description

This dataset contains the employees in 15 economic sections (German Classification of Economic Activities WZ2008) for the city Goettingen and Germany regarding the years 2008-2017 (date: 30 June each year).

Usage

data("Goettingen")

Format

A data frame with 16 observations on the following 22 variables.

WZ2008_Code

a factor containing the code of the industry (15 economic sections from the German Classification of Economic Activities WZ2008 + total employees), in German language

WZ2008_Name

a factor containing the name of the industry (15 economic sections from the German Classification of Economic Activities WZ2008 + total employees), in German language

Goettingen2008

industry employees in the city of Goettingen 2008

Goettingen2009

industry employees in the city of Goettingen 2009

Goettingen2010

industry employees in the city of Goettingen 2010

Goettingen2011

industry employees in the city of Goettingen 2011

Goettingen2012

industry employees in the city of Goettingen 2012

Goettingen2013

industry employees in the city of Goettingen 2013

Goettingen2014

industry employees in the city of Goettingen 2014

Goettingen2015

industry employees in the city of Goettingen 2015

Goettingen2016

industry employees in the city of Goettingen 2016

Goettingen2017

industry employees in the city of Goettingen 2017

BRD2008

industry employees in Germany 2008

BRD2009

industry employees in Germany 2009

BRD2010

industry employees in Germany 2010

BRD2011

industry employees in Germany 2011

BRD2012

industry employees in Germany 2012

BRD2013

industry employees in Germany 2013

BRD2014

industry employees in Germany 2014

BRD2015

industry employees in Germany 2015

BRD2016

industry employees in Germany 2016

BRD2017

industry employees in Germany 2017

Source

Bundesagentur fuer Arbeit (2018): “Beschaeftigungsstatistik, Beschaeftigte nach Wirtschaftszweigen (WZ 2008) (Zeitreihe Quartalszahlen) in Deutschland”. https://statistik.arbeitsagentur.de/DE/Navigation/Statistiken/Fachstatistiken/Beschaeftigung/Beschaeftigung-Nav.html (accessed October 10, 2018). Own postprocessing (filtering and aggregation).

Stadt Goettingen - Referat Statistik und Wahlen (2008): “Stadt Goettingen: Beschaeftigte nach Wirtschaftsbereichen und Wirtschaftsabschnitten 1980 bis 2018. Table: IS 071.20”. https://duva-stg-extern.kdgoe.de/Informationsportal/Dateien/071.20-2018.pdf (accessed November 21, 2019).

References

Bundesagentur fuer Arbeit (2018): “Beschaeftigungsstatistik, Beschaeftigte nach Wirtschaftszweigen (WZ 2008) (Zeitreihe Quartalszahlen) in Deutschland”. https://statistik.arbeitsagentur.de/DE/Navigation/Statistiken/Fachstatistiken/Beschaeftigung/Beschaeftigung-Nav.html (accessed October 10, 2018).

Federal Statistical Office Germany (2008): “Classification of Economic Activities, Edition 2008 (WZ 2008)”. https://www.klassifikationsserver.de/klassService/jsp/common/url.jsf?variant=wz2008&lang=EN (accessed June 07, 2019).

Stadt Goettingen - Referat Statistik und Wahlen (2008): “Stadt Goettingen: Beschaeftigte nach Wirtschaftsbereichen und Wirtschaftsabschnitten 1980 bis 2018. Table: IS 071.20”. https://duva-stg-extern.kdgoe.de/Informationsportal/Dateien/071.20-2018.pdf (accessed November 21, 2019).

Examples

data(Goettingen)

# Location quotients for Goettingen 2017:
locq (Goettingen$Goettingen2017[2:16], Goettingen$Goettingen2017[1], 
Goettingen$BRD2017[2:16], Goettingen$BRD2017[1])

# Gini coefficient of regional specialization 2017:
gini.spec(Goettingen$Goettingen2017[2:16], Goettingen$BRD2017[2:16])

# Krugman coefficient of regional specialization 2017:
krugman.spec(Goettingen$Goettingen2017[2:16], Goettingen$BRD2017[2:16])

Healthcare providers in South Lower Saxony

Description

Dataset with healthcare providers (general practitioners, psychotherapists, pharmacies) in two German counties (Goettingen and Northeim)

Usage

data("GoettingenHealth1")

Format

A data frame with 617 observations on the following 5 variables.

location

a numeric vector with unique IDs of the healthcare providers

lat

Latitude

lon

Longitude

type

Type of healthcare provider: general practitioners (phyh_gen), psychotherapists (psych) or pharmacies (pharm)

district

a numeric vector containing the IDs of the district the specific provider is located in

Source

Wieland T./Dittrich, C. (2016): “Bestands- und Erreichbarkeitsanalyse regionaler Gesundheitseinrichtungen in der Gesundheitsregion Goettingn”. Research report, Georg-August-Universitaet Goeottingen, Geographisches Institut, Abteilung Humangeographie. http://webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/pub/mon/2016/3-wieland.pdf.

References

Wieland T./Dittrich, C. (2016): “Bestands- und Erreichbarkeitsanalyse regionaler Gesundheitseinrichtungen in der Gesundheitsregion Goettingn”. Research report, Georg-August-Universitaet Goeottingen, Geographisches Institut, Abteilung Humangeographie. http://webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/pub/mon/2016/3-wieland.pdf.

Examples

## Not run: 
data(GoettingenHealth1)
# general practitioners, psychotherapists and pharmacies

area_goe <- 1753000000
# area of Landkreis Goettingen (sqm)
area_nom <- 1267000000
# area of Landkreis Northeim (sqm)
area_gn <- area_goe+area_nom
sqrt(area_gn/pi)

# this takes some seconds
ripley(GoettingenHealth1[GoettingenHealth1$type == "phys_gen",], 
"location", "lat", "lon", area = area_gn, t.max = 30000, t.sep = 300)

ripley(GoettingenHealth1[GoettingenHealth1$type == "pharm",], 
"location", "lat", "lon", area = area_gn, t.max = 30000, t.sep = 300)

ripley(GoettingenHealth1[GoettingenHealth1$type == "psych",], 
"location", "lat", "lon", area = area_gn, t.max = 30000, t.sep = 300)

## End(Not run)

Healthcare provision in South Lower Saxony

Description

Dataset with districts in two German counties (Goettingen and Northeim) and the corresponding healthcare providers (general practitioners, psychotherapists, pharmacies) and population size

Usage

data("GoettingenHealth2")

Format

A data frame with 420 observations on the following 7 variables.

district

a numeric vector containing the IDs of the district

pop

no. of inhabitants

lat

Latitude

lon

Longitude

phys_gen

no. of general practitioners

psych

no. of psychotherapists

pharm

no. of pharmacies

Source

Wieland T./Dittrich, C. (2016): “Bestands- und Erreichbarkeitsanalyse regionaler Gesundheitseinrichtungen in der Gesundheitsregion Goettingn”. Research report, Georg-August-Universitaet Goeottingen, Geographisches Institut, Abteilung Humangeographie. http://webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/pub/mon/2016/3-wieland.pdf.

References

Wieland T./Dittrich, C. (2016): “Bestands- und Erreichbarkeitsanalyse regionaler Gesundheitseinrichtungen in der Gesundheitsregion Goettingn”. Research report, Georg-August-Universitaet Goeottingen, Geographisches Institut, Abteilung Humangeographie. http://webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/pub/mon/2016/3-wieland.pdf.

Examples

data(GoettingenHealth2)
# districts with healthcare providers and population size

williamson((GoettingenHealth2$phys_gen/GoettingenHealth2$pop), 
GoettingenHealth2$pop)

Growth rates

Description

This function calculates the growth from two input numeric vectors

Usage

growth(val1, val2, growth.type = "growth",
output = "rate", rate.perc = FALSE, log.rate = FALSE, 
factor.mean = "mean", time.periods = NULL)

Arguments

val1

First numeric vector (e.g. employment at time tt)

val2

Second numeric vector (e.g. employment at time tt) or data frame for times t+1, t+2, t+3, ..., t+n

growth.type

Type of growth value that has to be calculated (absolute values or growth rate)

output

Type of output in the case of several years: growth rate (default: output = "rate") or annual values (output = "annual")

rate.perc

Logical argument that indicates whether growth rates are expressed in percent or not

log.rate

Logical argument that indicates whether growth rates are logged or not

factor.mean

If growth factors are returned: arithmetic mean (factor.mean = "mean") or geometric mean (factor.mean = "geom")

time.periods

No. of regarded time periods (for average growth rates)

Value

A numeric vector containing the growth rates in the same order as stated

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

Examples

# Example from Farhauer/Kroell (2013):
region_A_t <- c(90,20,10,60)
region_A_t1 <- c(100,40,10,55)
# data for region A (time t and t+1)
nation_X_t <- c(400,150,150,400)
nation_X_t1 <- c(440,210,135,480)
# data for the national economy (time t and t+1)
growth(region_A_t, region_A_t1)

data(Freiburg)
# Loads the data
growth(Freiburg$e_Freiburg2008, Freiburg$e_Freiburg2014, growth.type = "rate")
# Industry-specific growth rates for Freiburg 2008 to 2014

Hansen accessibility

Description

Calculating the Hansen accessibility for given origins and destinations

Usage

hansen(od_dataset, origins, destinations, attrac, dist, gamma = 1, lambda = -2, 
atype = "pow", dtype = "pow", gamma2 = NULL, lambda2 = NULL, dist_const = 0, 
dist_max = NULL, extract_local = FALSE, accnorm = FALSE, check_df = TRUE,
print.results = TRUE)

Arguments

od_dataset

an interaction matrix which is a data.frame containing the origins, destinations, the distances between them and a size variable for the opportunities of the destinations

origins

the column in the interaction matrix od_dataset containing the origins

destinations

the column in the interaction matrix od_dataset containing the destinations

attrac

the column in the interaction matrix od_dataset containing the "attractivity" variable of the destinations (e.g. no. of opportunities)

dist

the column in the interaction matrix od_dataset containing the transport costs (e.g. travelling time, distance)

gamma

a single numeric value for the exponential weighting (γ\gamma) of size (default: 1)

lambda

a single numeric value for the exponential weighting (λ\lambda) of distance (transport costs, default: -2)

atype

Type of attractivity weighting function: atype = "pow" (power function), atype = "exp" (exponential function) or atype = "logistic" (default: atype = "pow")

dtype

Type of distance weighting function: dtype = "pow" (power function), dtype = "exp" (exponential function) or dtype = "logistic" (default: dtype = "pow")

gamma2

if atype = "logistic" a second γ\gamma parameter is needed

lambda2

if dtype = "logistic" a second λ\lambda parameter is needed

dist_const

a numeric value of a constant to be added to the transport costs (e.g. 1)

dist_max

a numeric value of a maximal value of transport costs for the opportunities to be recognized

extract_local

logical argument that indicates if the start points should be included in the analysis or not (if i=ji=j). Default value: extract_local = FALSE

accnorm

logical argument that indicates if the Hansen accessibility should be standardized

check_df

logical argument that indicates if the given dataset is checked for correct input, only for internal use, should not be deselected (default: TRUE)

print.results

logical argument that indicates if the results are shown (default: TRUE)

Details

Accessibility and the inhibiting effect of transport costs on spatial interactions belong to the key concepts of economic geography (Aoyama et al. 2011). The Hansen accessibility (Hansen 1959) can be regarded as a potential model of spatial interaction that describes accessibility as the sum of all opportunities OO in the regions jj, OjO_{j}, weighted by distance or other types of transport costs from the origins, ii, to them, dijd_{ij}: Ai=jOjf(dij)A_{i} = \sum_{j}{O_{j} f(d_{ij})}. The distance/travel time is weighted by a distance decay function (f(dij)f(d_{ij})) to reflect the disutility (opportunity costs) of distance. From a microeconomic perspective, the accessibility of a region or zone can be seen as the sum of all utilities of every opportunity outgoing from given starting points, given an utility function containing the opportunities (utility) and transport costs (disutility) (Orpana/Lampinen 2003). As the accessibility model originally comes from urban land use theory, it can also be used to model spatial concentration/agglomeration, e.g. to quantify the rate of agglomeration of retail locations (Orpana/Lampinen 2003, Wieland 2015).

Originally the weighting function of distance is not explicitly stated and the "attractivities" (e.g. size of the activity at the destinations) is not weighted. These specifications are relaxed is this function, so both variables can be weighted by a power, exponential or logistic function. If accnorm = TRUE, the Hansen accessibility is standardized by weighting the non-standardized values by the sum of all opportunities without regarding transport costs; the standardized Hansen accessibility has a range between 0 and 1.

Value

A list containing the following objects:

origins

A data frame containing the origins

accessibility

A data frame containing the calculatedaccessibility values (optional: standardized accessibilities)

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Aoyama, Y./Murphy, J. T./Hanson, S. (2011): “Key Concepts in Economic Geography”. London : SAGE.

Hansen, W. G. (1959): “How Accessibility Shapes Land Use”. In: Journal of the American Institute of Planners, 25, 2, p. 73-76.

Orpana, T./Lampinen, J. (2003): “Building spatial choice models from aggregate data”. In: Journal of Regional Science, 43, 2, p. 319-347.

Wieland, T. (2015): “Raeumliches Einkaufsverhalten und Standortpolitik im Einzelhandel unter Beruecksichtigung von Agglomerationseffekten. Theoretische Erklaerungsansaetze, modellanalytische Zugaenge und eine empirisch-oekonometrische Marktgebietsanalyse anhand eines Fallbeispiels aus dem laendlichen Raum Ostwestfalens/Suedniedersachsens”. Geographische Handelsforschung, 23. 289 pages. Mannheim : MetaGIS.

See Also

converse, dist.calc, dist.mat, dist.buf, huff, reilly

Examples

# Example from Levy/Weitz (2009):
# Data for the existing and the new location
locations <- c("Existing Store", "New Store")
S_j <- c(5000, 10000)
location_data <- data.frame(locations, S_j)
# Data for the two communities (Rock Creek and Oak Hammock)
communities <- c("Rock Creek", "Oak Hammock")
C_i <- c(5000000, 3000000)
community_data <- data.frame(communities, C_i)
# Combining location and submarket data in the interaction matrix
interactionmatrix <- merge (community_data, location_data)
# Adding driving time:
interactionmatrix[1,5] <- 10
interactionmatrix[2,5] <- 5
interactionmatrix[3,5] <- 5
interactionmatrix[4,5] <- 15
colnames(interactionmatrix) <- c("communities", "C_i", "locations", "S_j", "d_ij")
shoppingcenters1 <- interactionmatrix
huff_shares <- huff(shoppingcenters1, "communities", "locations", "S_j", "d_ij")
# Market shares of the new location:
huff_shares$ijmatrix[huff_shares$ijmatrix$locations == "New Store",]
# Hansen accessibility for Oak Hammock and Rock Creek:
# hansen (huff_shares$ijmatrix, "communities", "locations", "S_j", "d_ij")

Herfindahl-Hirschman coefficient

Description

Calculating the Herfindahl-Hirschman coefficient of concentration, standardized and non-standardized

Usage

herf(x, coefnorm = FALSE, output = "HHI", na.rm = TRUE)

Arguments

x

A numeric vector (e.g. dataset of sales turnover or size of firms)

coefnorm

logical argument that indicates if the function output is the non-standardized or the standardized Herfindahl-Hirschman coefficient (default: coefnorm = FALSE, that means the non-standardized Herfindahl-Hirschman coefficient is returned)

output

argument to state the output. If output = "HHI" (default), the Herfindahl-Hirschman coefficient is returned (standardized or non-standardized). If output = "eq", the Herfindahl-Hirschman coefficient equivalent number is returned

na.rm

logical argument that indicates whether NA values should be excluded before computing results

Details

The Herfindahl-Hirschman coefficient is a popular measure of statistical dispersion, especially used for analyzing concentration in markets, regarding sales turnovers or sizes of nn competing firms in an industry. This indicator is especially used as a measure of market power and distortions of competition in the governmental competition policy (Roberts 2014). But the coefficient is also utilized as a measure of geographic concentration of industries (Lessmann 2005, Nakamura/Morrison Paul 2009).

The coefficient (HHIHHI) varies between 1n\frac{1}{n} (parity resp. no concentration) and 11 (complete concentration). Because the minimum of HHIHHI is not equal to 0, also a standardized coefficient (HHIHHI*) with a minimum equal to 0 can be calculated alternatively. The equivalent number (which is the inverse of the Herfindahl-Hirschman coefficient) reflects the theoretical number of economic objects (normally firms) where a calculated coefficient is 1n\frac{1}{n}, which means parity (Doersam 2004). In a regional context, the inverse of HHI is also used as a measure of diversity (Duranton/Puga 2000).

Value

A single numeric value of the Herfindahl-Hirschman coefficient (1n<HHI<1\frac{1}{n} < HHI < 1) or the standardized Herfindahl-Hirschman coefficient (0<HHI<10 < HHI* < 1) or the Herfindahl-Hirschman coefficient equivalent number (Heq>=1H_{eq} >= 1).

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Doersam, P. (2004): “Wirtschaftsstatistik anschaulich dargestellt”. Heidenau : PD-Verlag.

Duranton, G./Puga, D. (2000): “Diversity and Specialisation in Cities: Why, Where and When Does it Matter?”. In: Urban Studies, 37, 3, p. 533-555.

Lessmann, C. (2005): “Regionale Disparitaeten in Deutschland und ausgesuchten OECD-Staaten im Vergleich”. ifo Dresden berichtet, 3/2005. https://www.ifo.de/DocDL/ifodb_2005_3_25-33.pdf.

Nakamura, R./Morrison Paul, C. J. (2009): “Measuring agglomeration”. In: Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (eds.): Handbook of Regional Growth and Development Theories. Cheltenham: Elgar. p. 305-328.

Roberts, T. (2014): “When Bigger Is Better: A Critique of the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index's Use to Evaluate Mergers in Network Industries”. In: Pace Law Review, 34, 2, p. 894-946.

See Also

cv, gini

Examples

# Example from Doersam (2004):
sales <- c(20,50,20,10)
# sales turnover of four car manufacturing companies
herf(sales)
# returns the non-standardized HHI (0.34)
herf(sales, coefnorm=TRUE)
# returns the standardized HHI (0.12)
herf(sales, output = "eq")
# returns the HHI equivalent number (2.94)

# Regional disparities in Germany:
gdp <- c(460.69, 549.19, 124.16, 65.29, 31.59, 109.27, 263.44, 39.87, 258.53, 
645.59, 131.95, 35.03, 112.66, 56.22, 85.61, 56.81)
# GDP of german regions 2015 (in billion EUR)
herf(gdp)
# returns the HHI (0.125)

Hoover Concentration Index

Description

Calculating the Hoover Concentration Index with respect to regional income (e.g. GDP) and population

Usage

hoover(x, ref = NULL, weighting = NULL, output = "HC", na.rm = TRUE)

Arguments

x

A numeric vector (dataset of regional income, e.g. GDP)

ref

A numeric vector containing the reference distribution for the Hoover Index, e.g. population. If reg = NULL, the reference distribution is set to 1/n1/n

weighting

A numeric containing the weightings for the Hoover Index, e.g. population

output

Default option is the output of the Hoover Index. If output = "data", the corresponding data table is returned instead

na.rm

logical argument that indicates whether NA values should be excluded before computing results

Details

The Hoover Concentration Index (CICI) measures the economic concentration of income across space by comparing the share of income (e.g. GDP - Gross Domestic Product) with the share of population. The index varies between 0 (no inequality/concentration) and 1 (complete inequality/concentration). It can be used for economic inequality and/or regional disparities (Huang/Leung 2009).

Value

A single numeric value of the Hoover Concentration Index (0<CI<10 < CI < 1).

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Bahrenberg, G./Giese, E./Mevenkamp, N./Nipper, J. (2010): “Statistische Methoden in der Geographie. Band 1: Univariate und bivariate Statistik”. Stuttgart: Borntraeger.

Huang, Y./Leung, Y. (2009): “Measuring Regional Inequality: A Comparison of Coefficient of Variation and Hoover Concentration Index”. In: In: The Open Geography Journal, 2, p. 25-34.

Portnov, B.A./Felsenstein, D. (2010): “On the suitability of income inequality measures for regional analysis: Some evidence from simulation analysis and bootstrapping tests”. In: Socio-Economic Planning Sciences, 44, 4, p. 212-219.

See Also

cv, gini, herf, theil, atkinson, coulter, disp

Examples

# Regional disparities in Germany:
gdp <- c(460.69, 549.19, 124.16, 65.29, 31.59, 109.27, 263.44, 39.87, 258.53, 
645.59, 131.95, 35.03, 112.66, 56.22, 85.61, 56.81)
# GDP of german regions 2015 (in billion EUR)
pop <- pop <- c(10879618, 12843514, 3520031, 2484826, 671489, 1787408, 6176172, 
1612362, 7926599, 17865516, 4052803, 995597, 4084851, 2245470, 2858714, 2170714)
# population of german regions 2015
hoover(gdp, pop)

Howard-Newman-Tarp colocation index

Description

Calculating the colocation index (CL) by Howard, Newman and Tarp for two industries

Usage

howard.cl(k, industry, region, industry1, industry2, e_k = NULL)

Arguments

k

a vector containing the IDs/names of firms kk

industry

a vector containing the IDs/names of the industries ii

region

a vector containing the IDs/names of the regions jj

industry1

Regarded industry 1 (out of the industry vector)

industry2

Regarded industry 2 (out of the industry vector)

e_k

Employment of firm kk

Details

The Howard-Newman-Tarp colocation index (CLCL) is standardized (0CL10 \le CL \le 1). Processing time depends on the number of firms.

Value

A single value of CLCL

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Howard, E./Newman, C./Tarp, F. (2016): “Measuring industry coagglomeration and identifying the driving forces”. In: Journal of Economic Geography, 16, 5, p. 1055-1078.

See Also

howard.xcl, howard.xcl2, ellison.c, ellison.c2

Examples

# example from Howard et al. (2016):
firms <- 1:6
industries <- c("A", "B", "A", "B", "A", "B")
locations <- c("X", "X", "X", "Y", "Y", "X")

howard.cl(firms, industries, locations, industry1 = "A", 
industry2 = "B")

Howard-Newman-Tarp excess colocation (XCL) index

Description

Calculating the excess colocation (XCL) index by Howard, Newman and Tarp for two industries

Usage

howard.xcl(k, industry, region, industry1, industry2, no.samples = 50, e_k = NULL)

Arguments

k

a vector containing the IDs/names of firms kk

industry

a vector containing the IDs/names of the industries ii

region

a vector containing the IDs/names of the regions jj

industry1

Regarded industry 1 (out of the industry vector)

industry2

Regarded industry 2 (out of the industry vector)

no.samples

Number of samples for the counterfactual firm allocation via bootstrapping

e_k

Employment of firm kk

Details

The Howard-Newman-Tarp excess colocation index (XCLXCL) is standardized (1CL1-1 \le CL \le 1). The rationale behind is that the CL index (see howard.cl) is compared to a counterfactual (random) location pattern which is constructed via bootstrapping. Processing time depends on the number of firms and the number of samples.

Value

A single value of XCLXCL

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Howard, E./Newman, C./Tarp, F. (2016): “Measuring industry coagglomeration and identifying the driving forces”. In: Journal of Economic Geography, 16, 5, p. 1055-1078.

See Also

howard.cl, howard.xcl2, ellison.c, ellison.c2

Examples

# example from Howard et al. (2016):
firms <- 1:6
industries <- c("A", "B", "A", "B", "A", "B")
locations <- c("X", "X", "X", "Y", "Y", "X")

howard.xcl(firms, industries, locations, industry1 = "A", 
industry2 = "B")

Howard-Newman-Tarp excess colocation (XCL) index

Description

Calculating the excess colocation (XCL) index by Howard, Newman and Tarp for a given number of industries

Usage

howard.xcl2(k, industry, region, print.results = TRUE)

Arguments

k

a vector containing the IDs/names of firms kk

industry

a vector containing the IDs/names of the industries ii

region

a vector containing the IDs/names of the regions jj

print.results

logical argument that indicates whether the calculated values are printed or not

Details

The Howard-Newman-Tarp excess colocation index (XCLXCL) is standardized (1CL1-1 \le CL \le 1). The rationale behind is that the CL index (see howard.cl) is compared to a counterfactual (random) location pattern which is constructed via bootstrapping. Processing time depends on the number of firms and the number of samples. This function takes a while even for a relatively small number of industries!

Value

A matrix with II rows (one for each industry-industry combination) containing the XCLXCL values

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Howard, E./Newman, C./Tarp, F. (2016): “Measuring industry coagglomeration and identifying the driving forces”. In: Journal of Economic Geography, 16, 5, p. 1055-1078.

See Also

howard.cl, howard.xcl2, ellison.c, ellison.c2

Examples

## Not run: 
# example data from Farhauer/Kroell (2014):
data (FK2014_EGC)

howard.xcl2 (FK2014_EGC$firm, FK2014_EGC$industry, 
FK2014_EGC$region)
# this may take a while!

## End(Not run)

Huff model

Description

Calculating market areas using the probabilistic market area model by Huff

Usage

huff(huffdataset, origins, locations, attrac, dist, gamma = 1, lambda = -2, 
atype = "pow", dtype = "pow", gamma2 = NULL, lambda2 = NULL,  
localmarket_dataset = NULL, origin_id = NULL, localmarket = NULL, 
check_df = TRUE)

Arguments

huffdataset

an interaction matrix which is a data.frame containing the origins, locations and the explanatory variables

origins

the column in the interaction matrix huffdataset containing the origins (e.g. ZIP codes)

locations

the column in the interaction matrix huffdataset containing the locations (e.g. store codes)

attrac

the column in the interaction matrix huffdataset containing the attractivity variable (e.g. sales area)

dist

the column in the interaction matrix huffdataset containing the transport costs (e.g. travelling time)

gamma

a single numeric value for the exponential weighting of size (default: 1)

lambda

a single numeric value for the exponential weighting of distance (transport costs, default: -2)

atype

Type of attractivity weighting function: atype = "pow" (power function), atype = "exp" (exponential function) or atype = "logistic" (default: atype = "pow")

dtype

Type of distance weighting function: dtype = "pow" (power function), dtype = "exp" (exponential function) or dtype = "logistic" (default: dtype = "pow")

gamma2

if atype = "logistic" a second γ\gamma parameter is needed

lambda2

if dtype = "logistic" a second λ\lambda parameter is needed

localmarket_dataset

if output = "total", a data.frame is needed which contains data about the origins

origin_id

the ID variable of the origins in localmarket_dataset

localmarket

the customer/purchasing power potential of the origins in localmarket_dataset

check_df

logical argument that indicates if the given dataset is checked for correct input, only for internal use, should not be deselected (default: TRUE)

Details

The Huff Model (Huff 1962, 1963, 1964) is the most popular spatial interaction model for retailing and services and belongs to the family of probabilistic market area models. The basic idea of the model is that consumer decisions are not deterministic but probabilistic, so the decision of customers for a shopping location in a competitive environment cannot be predicted exactly. The results of the model are probabilities for these decisions, which can be interpreted as market shares of the regarded locations (jj) in the customer origins (ii), pijp_{ij}, which can be regarded as an equilibrium solution with logically consistent market shares (0 < pijp_{ij} < 1, j=1npij=1\sum_{j=1}^n{p_{ij} = 1}). From a theoretical perspective, the model is based on an utility function with two explanatory variables ("attractivity" of the locations, transport costs between origins and locations), which are weighted by an exponent: Uij=AjγdijλU_{ij}=A_{j}^\gamma d_{ij}^{-\lambda}. This specification is relaxed is this case, so both variables can be weighted by a power, exponential or logistic function.

This function computes the market shares from a given interaction matrix and given weighting parameters. The function returns an estimated interaction matrix. If local market information about the origins (e.g. purchasing power, population size etc.) is stated, the location total turnovers are filed in another data.frame. Note that each attractivity or distance value must be greater than zero.

Value

A list containing the following objects:

huffmat

A data frame containing the Huff interaction matrix

totals

If total turnovers are estimated: a data frame containing the total values (turnovers) of each location

Note

This function contains code from the authors' package MCI.

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Berman, B. R./Evans, J. R. (2012): “Retail Management: A Strategic Approach”. 12th edition. Bosten : Pearson.

Huff, D. L. (1962): “Determination of Intra-Urban Retail Trade Areas”. Los Angeles : University of California.

Huff, D. L. (1963): “A Probabilistic Analysis of Shopping Center Trade Areas”. In: Land Economics, 39, 1, p. 81-90.

Huff, D. L. (1964): “Defining and Estimating a Trading Area”. In: Journal of Marketing, 28, 4, p. 34-38.

Levy, M./Weitz, B. A. (2012): “Retailing management”. 8th edition. New York : McGraw-Hill Irwin.

Loeffler, G. (1998): “Market areas - a methodological reflection on their boundaries”. In: GeoJournal, 45, 4, p. 265-272.

Wieland, T. (2015): “Nahversorgung im Kontext raumoekonomischer Entwicklungen im Lebensmitteleinzelhandel - Konzeption und Durchfuehrung einer GIS-gestuetzten Analyse der Strukturen des Lebensmitteleinzelhandels und der Nahversorgung in Freiburg im Breisgau”. Projektbericht. Goettingen : GOEDOC, Dokumenten- und Publikationsserver der Georg-August-Universitaet Goettingen. http://webdoc.sub.gwdg.de/pub/mon/2015/5-wieland.pdf

See Also

converse, reilly, hansen

Examples

# Example from Levy/Weitz (2009):

# Data for the existing and the new location
locations <- c("Existing Store", "New Store")
S_j <- c(5000, 10000)
location_data <- data.frame(locations, S_j)

# Data for the two communities (Rock Creek and Oak Hammock)
communities <- c("Rock Creek", "Oak Hammock")
C_i <- c(5000000, 3000000)
community_data <- data.frame(communities, C_i)

# Combining location and submarket data in the interaction matrix
interactionmatrix <- merge (communities, location_data)
# Adding driving time:
interactionmatrix[1,4] <- 10
interactionmatrix[2,4] <- 5
interactionmatrix[3,4] <- 5
interactionmatrix[4,4] <- 15
colnames(interactionmatrix) <- c("communities", "locations", "S_j", "d_ij")

huff_shares <- huff(interactionmatrix, "communities", "locations", "S_j", "d_ij")
huff_shares
# Market shares of the new location:
huff_shares$ijmatrix[huff_shares$ijmatrix$locations == "New Store",]


huff_all <- huff(interactionmatrix, "communities", "locations", "S_j", "d_ij",
localmarket_dataset = community_data, origin_id = "communities", localmarket = "C_i")

huff_all

huff_all$totals

Krugman coefficient of spatial industry concentration for two industries

Description

Calculating the Krugman coefficient for the spatial concentration of two industries based on regional industry data (normally employment data)

Usage

krugman.conc(e_ij, e_uj)

Arguments

e_ij

a numeric vector with the employment of the industry ii in regions jj

e_uj

a numeric vector with the employment of the industry uu in region jj

Details

The Krugman coefficient of industry concentration (KiuK_{iu}) is a measure for the dissimilarity of the spatial structure of two industries (ii and uu) regarding the employment in the jj regions. The coefficient KiuK_{iu} varies between 0 (no concentration/same structure) and 2 (maximum difference, that means a complete other spatial structure of the industry compared to the others). The calculation is based on the formulae in Farhauer/Kroell (2013).

Value

A single numeric value (0<Kiu<20 < K_{iu} < 2)

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Farhauer, O./Kroell, A. (2013): “Standorttheorien: Regional- und Stadtoekonomik in Theorie und Praxis”. Wiesbaden : Springer.

Nakamura, R./Morrison Paul, C. J. (2009): “Measuring agglomeration”. In: Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (eds.): Handbook of Regional Growth and Development Theories. Cheltenham: Elgar. p. 305-328.

See Also

gini.conc, gini.spec, krugman.conc2, krugman.spec, krugman.spec2, locq

Examples

E_ij <- c(4388, 37489, 129423, 60941)
E_uj <- E_ij/2
krugman.conc(E_ij, E_uj)
# exactly the same structure (= no concentration)

Krugman coefficient of spatial industry concentration for more than two industries

Description

Calculating the Krugman coefficient for the spatial concentration of an industry based on regional industry data (normally employment data) compared with a vector of other industries

Usage

krugman.conc2(e_ij, e_uj)

Arguments

e_ij

a numeric vector with the employment of the industry ii in regions jj

e_uj

a data frame with the employment of the industry uu in jj regions

Details

The Krugman coefficient of industry concentration (KiK_{i}) is a measure for the dissimilarity of the spatial structure of one industry (ii) compared to several others (uu) regarding the employment in the jj regions. The coefficient KiuK_{iu} varies between 0 (no concentration/same structure) and 2 (maximum difference, that means a complete other spatial structure of the industry compared to the others). The calculation is based on the formulae in Farhauer/Kroell (2013).

Value

A single numeric value (0<Ki<20 < K_{i} < 2)

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Farhauer, O./Kroell, A. (2013): “Standorttheorien: Regional- und Stadtoekonomik in Theorie und Praxis”. Wiesbaden : Springer.

Nakamura, R./Morrison Paul, C. J. (2009): “Measuring agglomeration”. In: Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (eds.): Handbook of Regional Growth and Development Theories. Cheltenham: Elgar. p. 305-328.

See Also

gini.conc, gini.spec, krugman.conc, krugman.spec, krugman.spec2, locq

Examples

# Example from Farhauer/Kroell (2013):
Chemie <- c(20000,11000,31000,8000,20000)
Sozialwesen <- c(40000,10000,25000,9000,16000)
Elektronik <- c(10000,11000,14000,14000,13000)
Holz <- c(7000,7500,11000,1500,36000)
Bergbau <- c(4320, 7811, 3900, 2300, 47560)
# five industries
industries <- data.frame(Chemie, Sozialwesen, Elektronik, Holz)
# data frame with all comparison industries
krugman.conc2(Bergbau, industries)
# returns the Krugman coefficient for the concentration
# of the mining industry (Bergbau) compared to 
# chemistry (Chemie), social services (Sozialwesen), 
# electronics (Elektronik) and wood industry (Holz)
# 0.8619

Krugman coefficient of regional specialization for two regions

Description

Calculating the Krugman coefficient for the specialization of two regions based on regional industry data (normally employment data)

Usage

krugman.spec(e_ij, e_il)

Arguments

e_ij

a numeric vector with the employment of the industries ii in region jj

e_il

a numeric vector with the employment of the industries ii in region ll

Details

The Krugman coefficient of regional specialization (KjlK_{jl}) is a measure for the dissimilarity of the industrial structure of two regions (jj and ll) regarding the employment in the ii industries in these regions. The coefficient KjlK_{jl} varies between 0 (no specialization/same structure) and 2 (maximum difference, that means there is no single industry localized in both regions). The calculation is based on the formulae in Farhauer/Kroell (2013).

Value

A single numeric value (0<Kjl<20 < K_{jl} < 2)

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Farhauer, O./Kroell, A. (2013): “Standorttheorien: Regional- und Stadtoekonomik in Theorie und Praxis”. Wiesbaden : Springer.

Nakamura, R./Morrison Paul, C. J. (2009): “Measuring agglomeration”. In: Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (eds.): Handbook of Regional Growth and Development Theories. Cheltenham: Elgar. p. 305-328.

See Also

gini.conc, gini.spec, krugman.conc, krugman.conc2, krugman.spec2, locq

Examples

# Example from Farhauer/Kroell (2013), modified:
E_ij <- c(20,10,70,0,0)
# employment of five industries in region j
E_il <- c(0,0,0,60,40)
# employment of five industries in region l
krugman.spec(E_ij, E_il)
# results the specialization coefficient (2)

# Example Goettingen:
data(Goettingen)
krugman.spec(Goettingen$Goettingen2017[2:16], Goettingen$BRD2017[2:16])
# Returns the Krugman coefficient of regional specialization 2017 (0.4508469)

Krugman coefficient of regional specialization for more than two regions

Description

Calculating the Krugman coefficient for the specialization of one region based on regional industry data (normally employment data) compared with a vector of other regions

Usage

krugman.spec2(e_ij, e_il)

Arguments

e_ij

a numeric vector with the employment of the industries ii in region jj

e_il

a data frame with the employment of the industries ii in ll regions

Details

The Krugman coefficient of regional specialization (KjlK_{jl}) is a measure for the dissimilarity of the industrial structure of regions (jj and other regions, ll) regarding the employment in the ii industries in these regions. The coefficient KjlK_{jl} varies between 0 (no specialization/same structure) and 2 (maximum difference, that means there is no single industry localized in both regions).

Value

A single numeric value (0<Kjl<20 < K_{jl} < 2)

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Farhauer, O./Kroell, A. (2013): “Standorttheorien: Regional- und Stadtoekonomik in Theorie und Praxis”. Wiesbaden : Springer.

Nakamura, R./Morrison Paul, C. J. (2009): “Measuring agglomeration”. In: Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (eds.): Handbook of Regional Growth and Development Theories. Cheltenham: Elgar. p. 305-328.

See Also

gini.conc, gini.spec, krugman.spec, krugman.conc, krugman.conc2, locq

Examples

# Example from Farhauer/Kroell (2013):
Sweden <- c(45000, 15000, 32000, 10000, 30000)
Norway <- c(35000, 12000, 30000, 8000, 22000)
Denmark <- c(40000, 10000, 25000, 9000, 18000)
Finland <- c(30000, 11000, 18000, 3000, 13000)
Island <- c(40000, 6000, 11000, 2000, 12000)
# industry jobs in five industries for five countries
countries <- data.frame(Norway, Denmark, Finland, Island)
# data frame with all comparison countries
krugman.spec2(Sweden, countries)
# returns the Krugman coefficient for the specialization
# of sweden compared to Norway, Denmark, Finland and Island
# 0.1595

Litzenberger-Sternberg Cluster Index

Description

Calculating the Cluster Index by Litzenberger and Sternberg

Usage

litzenberger(e_ij, e_i, a_j, a, p_j, p, b_ij, b_i)

Arguments

e_ij

a single numeric value with the employment of industry ii in region jj

e_i

a single numeric value with the over-all employment in industry ii

a_j

a single numeric value of the area of region j

a

a single numeric value of the total area

p_j

a single numeric value of the population of region j

p

a single numeric value of the total population

b_ij

a single numeric value of the number of firms of industry ii in region jj

b_i

a single numeric value of the total number of firms of industry ii

Details

The Litzenberger-Sternberg Cluster Index is not standardized and depends on the number of regarded industries and regions.

Value

A single numeric value of (CICI).

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Farhauer, O./Kroell, A. (2014): “Standorttheorien: Regional- und Stadtoekonomik in Theorie und Praxis”. Wiesbaden : Springer.

Hoffmann J./Hirsch, S./Simons, J. (2017): “Identification of spatial agglomerations in the German food processing industry”. In: Papers in Regional Science, 96, 1, p. 139-162.

Litzenberger, T./Sternberg, R. (2006): “Der Clusterindex - eine Methodik zur Identifizierung regionaler Cluster am Beispiel deutscher Industriebranchen”. In: Geographische Zeitschrift, 94, 2, p. 209-224.

See Also

litzenberger2, gini.conc, gini.spec, locq, locq2, ellison.a, ellison.a2, ellison.c, ellison.c2

Examples

# Example from Farhauer/Kroell (2014):
litzenberger(e_ij = 1743, e_i = 5740, a_j = 50, 
a = 576, p_j = 488, p = 4621, b_ij = 35, b_i = 53)
# 21.87491

Litzenberger-Sternberg Cluster Index

Description

Calculating the Cluster Index by Litzenberger and Sternberg for a given number of II industries and JJ regions

Usage

litzenberger2(e_ij, industry.id, region.id, a_j, p_j, b_ij, 
CI.output = "mat", na.rm = TRUE)

Arguments

e_ij

a vector with the employment of industry ii in region jj

industry.id

a vector containing the IDs of the industries ii

region.id

a vector containing the IDs of the regions jj

a_j

a vector containing the areas of the regions jj

p_j

a vector containing the populations of the regions jj

b_ij

a vector containing the numbers of firms of industry ii in region jj

CI.output

Type of output: matrix (default: CI.output = "mat") or data frame (CI.output = "df")

na.rm

logical argument that indicates whether NA values should be excluded before computing results

Details

The Litzenberger-Sternberg Cluster Index is not standardized and depends on the number of regarded industries and regions.

Value

A matrix or data frame containing IxJIxJ values of CICI

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Farhauer, O./Kroell, A. (2014): “Standorttheorien: Regional- und Stadtoekonomik in Theorie und Praxis”. Wiesbaden : Springer.

Hoffmann J./Hirsch, S./Simons, J. (2017): “Identification of spatial agglomerations in the German food processing industry”. In: Papers in Regional Science, 96, 1, p. 139-162.

Litzenberger, T./Sternberg, R. (2006): “Der Clusterindex - eine Methodik zur Identifizierung regionaler Cluster am Beispiel deutscher Industriebranchen”. In: Geographische Zeitschrift, 94, 2, p. 209-224.

See Also

litzenberger, gini.conc, gini.spec, locq, locq2, ellison.a, ellison.a2, ellison.c, ellison.c2

Examples

data (G.regions.industries)

lss <- litzenberger2(G.regions.industries$emp_all, 
G.regions.industries$ind_code, G.regions.industries$region_code,
G.regions.industries$area_sqkm, G.regions.industries$pop,
G.regions.industries$firms, CI.output = "df")
# output as data frame

lss_sort <- lss[order(lss$CI, decreasing = TRUE),]
# Sort decreasing by size of CI

lss_sort[1:5,]

Beta regression coefficients

Description

Calculating the standardized (beta) regression coefficients of linear models

Usage

lm.beta(linmod, dummy.na = TRUE)

Arguments

linmod

A lm object (linear regression model) with more than one independent variable

dummy.na

logical argument that indicates if dummy variables should be ignored when calculating the beta weights (default: TRUE). Note that beta weights of dummy variables do not make any sense

Details

Standardized coefficients (beta coefficients) show how many standard deviations a dependent variable will change when the regarded independent variable is increased by a standard deviation. The β\beta values are used in multiple linear regression models to compare the real effect (power) of the independent variables when they are measured in different units. Note that β\beta values do not make any sense for dummy variables since they cannot change by a standard deviation.

Value

A list containing all independent variables and the corresponding standardized coefficients.

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Backhaus, K./Erichson, B./Plinke, W./Weiber, R. (2016): “Multivariate Analysemethoden: Eine anwendungsorientierte Einfuehrung”. Berlin: Springer.

Examples

x1 <- runif(100)
x2 <- runif(100)
# random values for two independent variables (x1, x2)
y <- runif(100)
# random values for the dependent variable (y)
testmodel <- lm(y~x1+x2)
# OLS regression
summary(testmodel)
# summary
lm.beta(testmodel)
# beta coefficients

Location quotient

Description

Calculating the location quotient (a.k.a. Hoover-Balassa quotient)

Usage

locq(e_ij, e_j, e_i, e, industry.names = NULL, plot.results = FALSE,
LQ.method = "m", plot.title = "Localization quotients", 
bar.col = "lightblue", line.col = "red", arg.size = 1)

Arguments

e_ij

a single numeric value or vector with the employment of industry/industries ii in region jj

e_j

a single numeric value with the over-all employment in region jj

e_i

a single numeric value or vector with the over-all employment in industry/industries ii

e

a single numeric value with the over-all employment in all regions

industry.names

Industry names (e.g. from the relevant statistical classification of economic activities)

plot.results

Logical argument that indicates if the results have to be plotted (only available if i>1i > 1)

LQ.method

Indicates whether the multiplicative (default: LQ.method = "m") or the additive LQ (LQ.method = "m") is computed

plot.title

If plot.results = TRUE: Plot title

bar.col

If plot.results = TRUE: Bar colour

line.col

If plot.results = TRUE: LQ1-line colour

arg.size

If plot.results = TRUE: Size of industry names in bar plot

Details

The location quotient is a simple measure for the concentration of an industry (ii) in a region (jj) and is also the mathematical basis for other related indicators in regional economics (e.g. gini.conc()). The function returns the value LQLQ which is equal to 1 if the concentration of the regarded industry is exactly the same as the over-all concentration (that means, it is proportionally represented in region jj). If the value of LQLQ is smaller (bigger) than 1, the industry is underrepresented (overrepresented). The function checks the input values for errors (i.e. if employment in a region is bigger than over-all employment).

Value

A single numeric value of (LQLQ) or a matrix with respect to all ii industries. Optional: plot.

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Farhauer, O./Kroell, A. (2013): “Standorttheorien: Regional- und Stadtoekonomik in Theorie und Praxis”. Wiesbaden : Springer.

Hoen A.R./Oosterhaven, J. (2006): “On the measure of comparative advantage”. In: The Annals of Regional Science, 40, 3, p. 677-691.

Nakamura, R./Morrison Paul, C. J. (2009): “Measuring agglomeration”. In: Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (eds.): Handbook of Regional Growth and Development Theories. Cheltenham: Elgar. p. 305-328.

O'Donoghue, D./Gleave, B. (2004): “A Note on Methods for Measuring Industrial Agglomeration”. In: Regional Studies, 38, 4, p. 419-427.

Tian, Z. (2013): “Measuring agglomeration using the standardized location quotient with a bootstrap method”. In: Journal of Regional Analysis and Policy, 43, 2, p. 186-197.

See Also

gini.conc, gini.spec, locq2

Examples

# Example from Farhauer/Kroell (2013):
locq (1714, 79006, 879213, 15593224)
# returns the location quotient (0.3847623)

# Location quotients for Goettingen 2017:
data(Goettingen)
locq (Goettingen$Goettingen2017[2:16], Goettingen$Goettingen2017[1], 
Goettingen$BRD2017[2:16], Goettingen$BRD2017[1])

Portfolio matrix for specialization and growth

Description

Portfolio matrix plot comparing two numeric vectors (here: specialization and growth)

Usage

locq.growth(e_ij1, e_ij2, e_i1, e_i2, industry.names = NULL, 
y.axis = "r", 
psize, psize.factor = 10, time.periods = NULL,
pmx = "Regional specialization", pmy = "Regional growth", 
pmtitle = "Portfolio matrix", pcol = NULL, pcol.border = NULL,
leg = FALSE, leg.fsize = 1, leg.col = NULL,
leg.x = 0, leg.y = y_min*1.5,
bg.col = "gray95", bgrid = TRUE, bgrid.col = "white", 
bgrid.size = 2, bgrid.type = "solid",
seg.x = 1, seg.y = 0)

Arguments

e_ij1

a numeric vector with ii values containing the employment in ii industries in region jj at time 1

e_ij2

a numeric vector with ii values containing the employment in ii industries in region jj at time 2

e_i1

a numeric vector with ii values containing the total employment in ii industries at time 1

e_i2

a numeric vector with ii values containing the total employment in ii industries at time 2

industry.names

Industry names (e.g. from the relevant statistical classification of economic activities)

y.axis

Declares which values shall be plotted on the Y axis: If y.axis = "r", the Y axis shows the regional growth. If y.axis = "n", the Y axis shows the national growth. To set both growths in ratio, choose y.axis = "rn" (regional vs. national growth)

psize

Point size in the portfolio matrix plot (mostly the absolute values of employment in ii industries in region jj at time 2)

psize.factor

Enlargement factor for the points in the plot

time.periods

No. of regarded time periods (for average growth rates)

pmx

Name of the X axis in the plot

pmy

Name of the Y axis in the plot

pmtitle

Plot title

pcol

Industry-specific point colors

pcol.border

Color of point border

leg

Logical argument that indicates if a legend has to be added to the plot

leg.fsize

If leg = TRUE: Font size in the plot legend

leg.col

No. of columns in the plot legend

leg.x

If leg = TRUE: X coordinate of the legend

leg.y

If leg = TRUE: Y coordinate of the legend

bg.col

Background color

bgrid

Logical argument that indicates if a grid has to be added to the plot

bgrid.col

If bgrid = TRUE: Color of the grid

bgrid.size

If bgrid = TRUE: Size of the grid

bgrid.type

If bgrid = TRUE: Type of the grid

seg.x

X coordinate of segmentation of the plot

seg.y

Y coordinate of segmentation of the plot

Details

The portfolio matrix is a graphic tool displaying the development of one variable compared to another variable. The plot shows the regarded variable on the xx axis and a variable with which it is confronted on the yy axis while the graph is divided in four quadrants. Originally, the portfolio matrix was developed by the Boston Consulting Group to analyze the performance of product lines in marketing, also known as the growth-share matrix. The quadrants show the performace of the regarded objects (stars, cash cows, question marks, dogs) (Henderson 1973). But the portfolio matrix can also be used to analyze/illustrate the world market integration of a region or a national economy by confronting e.g. the increase in world market share (xx axis) and the world trade growth (yy axis) (Baker et al. 2002). Another option is to analyze/illustrate the economic performance of a region (Howard 2007). E.g. it is possible to confront the growth of industries in a region with the all-over growth of these industries in the national economy.

This function is a special case of portfolio matrix, showing the regional specialization on the X axis instead of the regional growth (which can be plotted on the Y axis).

Value

A portfolio matrix plot.

Invisible: a list containing the following items:

portfolio.data

The data related to the plot

locq

The localization quotients for each year

growth

The growth values for each industry

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Baker, P./von Kirchbach, F./Mimouni, M./Pasteels, J.-M. (2002): “Analytical tools for enhancing the participation of developing countries in the Multilateral Trading System in the context of the Doha Development Agenda”. In: Aussenwirtschaft, 57, 3, p. 343-372.

Howard, D. (2007): “A regional economic performance matrix - an aid to regional economic policy development”. In: Journal of Economic and Social Policy, 11, 2, Art. 4.

Henderson, B. D. (1973): “The Experience Curve - Reviewed, IV. The Growth Share Matrix or The Product Portfolio”. The Boston Consulting Group (BCG).

See Also

locq, portfolio, shift, shiftd, shifti

Examples

data(Goettingen)
# Loads employment data for Goettingen and Germany (2008-2017)

locq.growth(Goettingen$Goettingen2008[2:16], Goettingen$Goettingen2017[2:16],
Goettingen$BRD2008[2:16], Goettingen$BRD2017[2:16], 
psize = Goettingen$Goettingen2017[2:16], 
industry.names = Goettingen$WA_WZ2008[2:16], pcol.border = "grey", 
leg = TRUE, leg.fsize = 0.4, leg.x = -0.2)

Location quotient

Description

Calculating the location quotient (a.k.a. Hoover-Balassa quotient) for a given number of II industries and JJ regions

Usage

locq2(e_ij, industry.id, region.id, LQ.norm = "none", 
LQ.output = "mat", na.rm = TRUE)

Arguments

e_ij

a vector with the employment of industry ii in region jj

industry.id

a vector containing the IDs of the industries ii

region.id

a vector containing the IDs of the regions jj

LQ.norm

Type of normalization of the location quotients: no normalization (default: LQ.norm = "none"), z values (LQ.norm = "OG") or z values of logged location quotients (LQ.norm = "T")

LQ.output

Type of output: matrix (default: CI.output = "mat") or data frame (CI.output = "df")

na.rm

logical argument that indicates whether NA values should be excluded before computing results

Details

The location quotient is a simple measure for the concentration of an industry (ii) in a region (jj) and is also the mathematical basis for other related indicators in regional economics (e.g. gini.conc()). The function returns the value LQLQ which is equal to 1 if the concentration of the regarded industry is exactly the same as the over-all concentration (that means, it is proportionally represented in region jj). If the value of LQLQ is smaller (bigger) than 1, the industry is underrepresented (overrepresented). The function checks the input values for errors (i.e. if employment in a region is bigger than over-all employment).

Two types of normalization are available: z values of the location quotients (O'Donoghue/Gleave 2004) or z values of logged location quotients (Tian 2013).

Value

A matrix or data frame containing IxJIxJ values of LQLQ

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Farhauer, O./Kroell, A. (2014): “Standorttheorien: Regional- und Stadtoekonomik in Theorie und Praxis”. Wiesbaden : Springer.

Hoen A.R./Oosterhaven, J. (2006): “On the measure of comparative advantage”. In: The Annals of Regional Science, 40, 3, p. 677-691.

Nakamura, R./Morrison Paul, C. J. (2009): “Measuring agglomeration”. In: Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (eds.): Handbook of Regional Growth and Development Theories. Cheltenham: Elgar. p. 305-328.

O'Donoghue, D./Gleave, B. (2004): “A Note on Methods for Measuring Industrial Agglomeration”. In: Regional Studies, 38, 4, p. 419-427.

Tian, Z. (2013): “Measuring agglomeration using the standardized location quotient with a bootstrap method”. In: Journal of Regional Analysis and Policy, 43, 2, p. 186-197.

See Also

litzenberger, gini.conc, gini.spec, locq, hoover, ellison.a, ellison.a2, ellison.c, ellison.c2

Examples

data (G.regions.industries)

lqs <- locq2(e_ij = G.regions.industries$emp_all, 
G.regions.industries$ind_code, G.regions.industries$region_code, 
LQ.output = "df")
# output as data frame

lqs_sort <- lqs[order(lqs$LQ, decreasing = TRUE),]
# Sort decreasing by size of LQ

lqs_sort[1:5,]

Lorenz curve

Description

Calculating and plotting the Lorenz curve

Usage

lorenz(x, weighting = NULL, z = NULL, na.rm = TRUE,
lcx = "% of objects", lcy = "% of regarded variable", 
lctitle = "Lorenz curve", le.col = "blue", lc.col = "black",
lsize = 1.5, ltype = "solid", bg.col = "gray95", bgrid = TRUE, 
bgrid.col = "white", bgrid.size = 2, bgrid.type = "solid",
lcg = FALSE, lcgn = FALSE, lcg.caption = NULL, lcg.lab.x = 0, 
lcg.lab.y = 1, add.lc = FALSE, plot.lc = TRUE)

Arguments

x

A numeric vector (e.g. dataset of household income, sales turnover or supply)

weighting

A numeric vector containing the weighting data (e.g. size of income classes when calculating a Lorenz curve for aggregated income data)

z

A numeric vector for (optionally) comparing the cumulative distribution

na.rm

logical argument that indicates whether NA values should be excluded before computing results

lcx

defines the x axis label

lcy

defines the y axis label

lctitle

defines the overall title of the Lorenz curve plot

le.col

defines the color of the diagonale (line of equality)

lc.col

defines the color of the Lorenz curve

lsize

defines the size of the lines (default: 1)

ltype

defines the type of the lines (default: "solid")

bg.col

defines the background color of the plot (default: "gray95")

bgrid

logical argument that indicates if a grid is shown in the plot

bgrid.col

if bgrid = TRUE (background grid), bgrid.col defines the color of the background grid (default: "white")

bgrid.size

if bgrid = TRUE (background grid), bgrid.size defines the size of the background grid (default: 2)

bgrid.type

if bgrid = TRUE (background grid), bgrid.type defines the type of lines of the background grid (default: "solid")

lcg

logical argument that indicates if the non-standardized Gini coefficient is displayed in the Lorenz curve plot

lcgn

logical argument that indicates if the standardized Gini coefficient is displayed in the Lorenz curve plot

lcg.caption

specifies the caption above the coefficients

lcg.lab.x

specifies the x coordinate of the label

lcg.lab.y

specifies the y coordinate of the label

add.lc

specifies if a new Lorenz curve is plotted (add.lc = "FALSE") or the plot is added to an existing Lorenz curve plot (add.lc = "TRUE")

plot.lc

logical argument that indicates if the Lorenz curve itself is plotted (if plot.lc = FALSE, only the line of equality is plotted))

Details

The Gini coefficient (Gini 1912) is a popular measure of statistical dispersion, especially used for analyzing inequality or concentration. The Lorenz curve (Lorenz 1905), though developed independently, can be regarded as a graphical representation of the degree of inequality/concentration calculated by the Gini coefficient (GG) and can also be used for additional interpretations of it. In an economic-geographical context, these methods are frequently used to analyse the concentration/inequality of income or wealth within countries (Aoyama et al. 2011). Other areas of application are analyzing regional disparities (Lessmann 2005, Nakamura 2008) and concentration in markets (sales turnover of competing firms) which makes Gini and Lorenz part of economic statistics in general (Doersam 2004, Roberts 2014).

The Gini coefficient (GG) varies between 0 (no inequality/concentration) and 1 (complete inequality/concentration). The Lorenz curve displays the deviations of the empirical distribution from a perfectly equal distribution as the difference between two graphs (the distribution curve and a diagonal line of perfect equality). This function calculates GG and plots the Lorenz curve optionally. As there are several ways to calculate the Gini coefficient, this function uses the formula given in Doersam (2004). Because the maximum of GG is not equal to 1, also a standardized coefficient (GG*) with a maximum equal to 1 can be calculated alternatively. If a Lorenz curve for aggregated data (e.g. income classes with averaged incomes) or the Lorenz curve has to be weighted, use a weighting vector (e.g. size of the income classes).

Value

A plot of the Lorenz curve.

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Aoyama, Y./Murphy, J. T./Hanson, S. (2011): “Key Concepts in Economic Geography”. London : SAGE.

Bahrenberg, G./Giese, E./Mevenkamp, N./Nipper, J. (2010): “Statistische Methoden in der Geographie. Band 1: Univariate und bivariate Statistik”. Stuttgart: Borntraeger.

Cerlani, L./Verme, P. (2012): “The origins of the Gini index: extracts from Variabilita e Mutabilita (1912) by Corrado Gini”. In: The Journal of Economic Inequality, 10, 3, p. 421-443.

Doersam, P. (2004): “Wirtschaftsstatistik anschaulich dargestellt”. Heidenau : PD-Verlag.

Gini, C. (1912): “Variabilita e Mutabilita”. Contributo allo Studio delle Distribuzioni e delle Relazioni Statistiche. Bologna : Cuppini.

Lessmann, C. (2005): “Regionale Disparitaeten in Deutschland und ausgesuchten OECD-Staaten im Vergleich”. ifo Dresden berichtet, 3/2005. https://www.ifo.de/DocDL/ifodb_2005_3_25-33.pdf.

Lorenz, M. O. (1905): “Methods of Measuring the Concentration of Wealth”. In: Publications of the American Statistical Association, 9, 70, p. 209-219.

Nakamura, R. (2008): “Agglomeration Effects on Regional Economic Disparities: A Comparison between the UK and Japan”. In: Urban Studies, 45, 9, p. 1947-1971.

Roberts, T. (2014): “When Bigger Is Better: A Critique of the Herfindahl-Hirschman Index's Use to Evaluate Mergers in Network Industries”. In: Pace Law Review, 34, 2, p. 894-946.

See Also

cv, gini.conc, gini.spec, herf, hoover

Examples

# Market concentration (example from Doersam 2004):
sales <- c(20,50,20,10)
# sales turnover of four car manufacturing companies
lorenz (sales, lcx = "percentage of companies", lcy = "percentrage of sales", 
lctitle = "Lorenz curve of sales", lcg = TRUE, lcgn = TRUE)
# plots the Lorenz curve with user-defined title and labels 
# including Gini coefficent

# Income classes (example from Doersam 2004):
income <- c(500, 1500, 2500, 4000, 7500, 15000)
# average income of 6 income classes
sizeofclass <- c(1000, 1200, 1600, 400, 200, 600)
# size of income classes
lorenz (income, weighting = sizeofclass, lcg = TRUE, lcgn = TRUE)
# plots the Lorenz curve with user-defined title and labels
# including Gini coefficent

# Regional disparities in Germany:
gdp <- c(460.69, 549.19, 124.16, 65.29, 31.59, 109.27, 263.44, 39.87, 258.53, 
645.59, 131.95, 35.03, 112.66, 56.22, 85.61, 56.81)
# GDP of german regions 2015 (in billion EUR)
lorenz (gdp, lcg = TRUE, lcgn = TRUE)
# plots the Lorenz curve with user-defined title and labels
# including Gini coefficent

Calculation of mean (extended)

Description

Calculating the arithmetic mean, weighted or non-weighted, or the geometric mean

Usage

mean2(x, weighting = NULL, output = "mean", na.rm = TRUE)

Arguments

x

a numeric vector

weighting

a numeric vector containing weighting data to compute the weighted arithmetic mean (instead of the non-weighted)

output

argument to specify the output (output = "mean" returns the arithmetic mean, output = "geom" returns the geometric mean)

na.rm

logical argument that whether NA values should be extracted or not

Details

This function uses the formula for the weighted arithmetic mean from Sheret (1984).

Value

Single numeric value. If output = "mean" and weighting is specified, the function returns a weighted arithmetic mean. If output = "geom", the geometric mean is returned.

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Bahrenberg, G./Giese, E./Mevenkamp, N./Nipper, J. (2010): “Statistische Methoden in der Geographie. Band 1: Univariate und bivariate Statistik”. Stuttgart: Borntraeger.

Sheret, M. (1984): “The Coefficient of Variation: Weighting Considerations”. In: Social Indicators Research, 15, 3, p. 289-295.

See Also

sd2

Examples

avector <- c(5, 17, 84, 55, 39)
mean(avector)
mean2(avector)
wvector <- c(9, 757, 44, 18, 682)
mean2 (avector, weighting = wvector)
mean2 (avector, output = "geom")

Mean square successive difference

Description

Calculating the mean square successive difference

Usage

mssd (x)

Arguments

x

a numeric vector arranged in chronological order

Details

The mean square successive difference, δ2\delta^2, is a dimensionless measure of variability over time (von Neumann et al. 1941). It can be used for assessing the volatility of a variable with respect to different subjects/groups.

Value

Single numeric value (the mean square successive difference, δ2\delta^2).

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Von Neumann, J./Kent, R. H./Bellinson, H. R./Hart, B. I. (1941): “The mean square successive difference”. In: The Annals of Mathematical Statistics, 12, 2, p. 153-162.

See Also

var2, sd2, cv

Examples

data1 <- c(10,10,10,20,20,20,30,30,30)
# stable growth
data2 <- c(20,10,30,10,30,20,30,20,10)
# high variability

# Means:
mean2(data1)
mean2(data2)
# Same means

# Standard deviation:
sd2(data1)
sd2(data2)
# Coefficient of variation:
cv(data1)
cv(data2)
# Measures of statistical dispersion are equal

mssd(data1)
mssd(data2)
# high differences in variability

Portfolio matrix

Description

Portfolio matrix plot comparing two numeric vectors

Usage

portfolio(e_ij1, e_ij2, e_i1, e_i2, industry.names = NULL, 
psize, psize.factor = 10, time.periods = NULL,
pmx = "Regional growth", pmy = "National growth", 
pmtitle = "Portfolio matrix", pcol = NULL, pcol.border = NULL,
leg = FALSE, leg.fsize = 1, leg.col = NULL,
leg.x = -max_val, leg.y = -max_val*1.5,
bg.col = "gray95", bgrid = TRUE, bgrid.col = "white", 
bgrid.size = 2, bgrid.type = "solid",
seg.x = 0, seg.y = 0)

Arguments

e_ij1

a numeric vector with ii values containing the employment in ii industries in region jj at time 1

e_ij2

a numeric vector with ii values containing the employment in ii industries in region jj at time 2

e_i1

a numeric vector with ii values containing the total employment in ii industries at time 1

e_i2

a numeric vector with ii values containing the total employment in ii industries at time 2

industry.names

Industry names (e.g. from the relevant statistical classification of economic activities)

psize

Point size in the portfolio matrix plot (mostly the absolute values of employment in ii industries in region jj at time 2)

psize.factor

Enlargement factor for the points in the plot

time.periods

No. of regarded time periods (for average growth rates)

pmx

Name of the X axis in the plot

pmy

Name of the Y axis in the plot

pmtitle

Plot title

pcol

Industry-specific point colors

pcol.border

Color of point border

leg

Logical argument that indicates if a legend has to be added to the plot

leg.fsize

If leg = TRUE: Font size in the plot legend

leg.col

No. of columns in the legend

leg.x

If leg = TRUE: X coordinate of the legend

leg.y

If leg = TRUE: Y coordinate of the legend

bg.col

Background color

bgrid

Logical argument that indicates if a grid has to be added to the plot

bgrid.col

If bgrid = TRUE: Color of the grid

bgrid.size

If bgrid = TRUE: Size of the grid

bgrid.type

If bgrid = TRUE: Type of the grid

seg.x

X coordinate of segmentation of the plot

seg.y

Y coordinate of segmentation of the plot

Details

The portfolio matrix is a graphic tool displaying the development of one variable compared to another variable. The plot shows the regarded variable on the xx axis and a variable with which it is confronted on the yy axis while the graph is divided in four quadrants. Originally, the portfolio matrix was developed by the Boston Consulting Group to analyze the performance of product lines in marketing, also known as the growth-share matrix. The quadrants show the performace of the regarded objects (stars, cash cows, question marks, dogs) (Henderson 1973). But the portfolio matrix can also be used to analyze/illustrate the world market integration of a region or a national economy by confronting e.g. the increase in world market share (xx axis) and the world trade growth (yy axis) (Baker et al. 2002). Another option is to analyze/illustrate the economic performance of a region (Howard 2007). E.g. it is possible to confront the growth of industries in a region with the all-over growth of these industries in the national economy.

Value

A portfolio matrix plot and a data frame containing the related data (invisible).

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Baker, P./von Kirchbach, F./Mimouni, M./Pasteels, J.-M. (2002): “Analytical tools for enhancing the participation of developing countries in the Multilateral Trading System in the context of the Doha Development Agenda”. In: Aussenwirtschaft, 57, 3, p. 343-372.

Howard, D. (2007): “A regional economic performance matrix - an aid to regional economic policy development”. In: Journal of Economic and Social Policy, 11, 2, Art. 4.

Henderson, B. D. (1973): “The Experience Curve - Reviewed, IV. The Growth Share Matrix or The Product Portfolio”. The Boston Consulting Group (BCG).

See Also

shift, shiftd, shifti

Examples

data(Freiburg)
# Loads employment data for Freiburg and Germany (2008 and 2014)

portfolio(Freiburg$e_Freiburg2008, Freiburg$e_Freiburg2014, 
Freiburg$e_Germany2008, Freiburg$e_Germany2014, 
industry.names = Freiburg$industry, Freiburg$e_Freiburg2014, psize.factor = 12,
pmx = "Freiburg", pmy = "Deutschland", pmtitle = "Freiburg und BRD", 
pcol = Freiburg$color, leg = TRUE, leg.fsize = 0.6, bgrid = TRUE, leg.y = -0.17)

Analysis of regional beta and sigma convergence

Description

This function provides the analysis of absolute and conditional regional economic beta convergence and sigma convergence for cross-sectional data. Beta convergence can be estimated using an OLS or NLS technique. Sigma convergence can be analyzed using ANOVA or trend regression.

Usage

rca(gdp1, time1, gdp2, time2, 
conditions = NULL, conditions.formula = NULL, conditions.startval = NULL, 
beta.estimate = "ols", beta.plot = FALSE, beta.plotPSize = 1, beta.plotPCol = "black", 
beta.plotLine = FALSE, beta.plotLineCol = "red", beta.plotX = "Ln (initial)", 
beta.plotY = "Ln (growth)", beta.plotTitle = "Beta convergence", beta.bgCol = "gray95", 
beta.bgrid = TRUE, beta.bgridCol = "white", beta.bgridSize = 2, beta.bgridType = "solid", 
sigma.type = "anova", sigma.measure = "sd", sigma.log = TRUE, sigma.weighting = NULL, 
sigma.issample = FALSE, sigma.plot = FALSE, sigma.plotLSize = 1, 
sigma.plotLineCol = "black", sigma.plotRLine = FALSE, sigma.plotRLineCol = "blue", 
sigma.Ymin = 0, sigma.plotX = "Time", sigma.plotY = "Variation", 
sigma.plotTitle = "Sigma convergence", sigma.bgCol = "gray95", sigma.bgrid = TRUE, 
sigma.bgridCol = "white", sigma.bgridSize = 2, sigma.bgridType = "solid")

Arguments

gdp1

A numeric vector containing the GDP per capita (or another economic variable) at time t

time1

A single value of time t (= the initial year)

gdp2

A numeric vector containing the GDP per capita (or another economic variable) at time t+1 or a data frame containing the GDPs per capita (or another economic variable) at time t+1, t+2, t+3, ..., t+n

time2

A single value of time t+1 or t_n, respectively

conditions

A data frame containing the conditions for conditional beta convergence

conditions.formula

If beta.estimate = "nls": A formula for the functional linkage of the conditions in the case of conditional beta convergence

conditions.startval

If beta.estimate = "nls": Starting values for the parameters of the conditions in the case of conditional beta convergence

beta.estimate

Beta estimate via ordinary least squares (OLS) or nonlinear least squares (NLS). Default: beta.estimate = "ols"

beta.plot

Boolean argument that indicates if a plot of beta convergence has to be created

beta.plotPSize

If beta.plot = TRUE: Point size in the beta convergence plot

beta.plotPCol

If beta.plot = TRUE: Point color in the beta convergence plot

beta.plotLine

If beta.plot = TRUE: Logical argument that indicates if a regression line has to be added to the plot

beta.plotLineCol

If beta.plot = TRUE and beta.plotLine = TRUE: Line color of regression line

beta.plotX

If beta.plot = TRUE: Name of the X axis

beta.plotY

If beta.plot = TRUE: Name of the Y axis

beta.plotTitle

If beta.plot = TRUE: Plot title

beta.bgCol

If beta.plot = TRUE: Plot background color

beta.bgrid

If beta.plot = TRUE: Logical argument that indicates if the plot contains a grid

beta.bgridCol

If beta.plot = TRUE and beta.bgrid = TRUE: Color of the grid

beta.bgridSize

If beta.plot = TRUE and beta.bgrid = TRUE: Size of the grid

beta.bgridType

If beta.plot = TRUE and beta.bgrid = TRUE: Type of the grid

sigma.type

Estimating sigma convergence via ANOVA (two years) or trend regression (more than two years). Default: sigma.type = "anova"

sigma.measure

argument that indicates how the sigma convergence should be measured. The default is output = "sd", which means that the standard deviation is used. If output = "var" or output = "cv", the variance or the coefficient of variation is used, respectively.

sigma.log

Logical argument. Per default (sigma.log = TRUE), also in the sigma convergence analysis, the economic variables are transformed by natural logarithm. If the original values should be used, state sigma.log = FALSE

sigma.weighting

If the measure of statistical dispersion in the sigma convergence analysis (coefficient of variation or standard deviation) should be weighted, a weighting vector has to be stated

sigma.issample

Logical argument that indicates if the dataset is a sample or the population (default: is.sample = FALSE, so the denominator of variance is nn)

sigma.plot

Logical argument that indicates if a plot of sigma convergence has to be created

sigma.plotLSize

If sigma.plot = TRUE: Line size of the sigma convergence plot

sigma.plotLineCol

If sigma.plot = TRUE: Line color of the sigma convergence plot

sigma.plotRLine

If sigma.plot = TRUE: Logical argument that indicates if a regression line has to be added to the plot

sigma.plotRLineCol

If sigma.plot = TRUE and sigma.plotRLine = TRUE: Color of the regression line

sigma.Ymin

If sigma.plot = TRUE: start value of the Y axis in the plot

sigma.plotX

If sigma.plot = TRUE: Name of the X axis

sigma.plotY

If sigma.plot = TRUE: Name of the Y axis

sigma.plotTitle

If sigma.plot = TRUE: Title of the plot

sigma.bgCol

If sigma.plot = TRUE: Plot background color

sigma.bgrid

If sigma.plot = TRUE: Logical argument that indicates if the plot contains a grid

sigma.bgridCol

If sigma.plot = TRUE and sigma.bgrid = TRUE: Color of the grid

sigma.bgridSize

If sigma.plot = TRUE and sigma.bgrid = TRUE: Size of the grid

sigma.bgridType

If sigma.plot = TRUE and sigma.bgrid = TRUE: Type of the grid

Details

From the regional economic perspective (in particular the neoclassical growth theory), regional disparities are expected to decline. This convergence can have different meanings: Sigma convergence (σ\sigma) means a harmonization of regional economic output or income over time, while beta convergence (β\beta) means a decline of dispersion because poor regions have a stronger economic growth than rich regions (Capello/Nijkamp 2009). Regardless of the theoretical assumptions of a harmonization in reality, the related analytical framework allows to analyze both types of convergence for cross-sectional data (GDP p.c. or another economic variable, yy, for ii regions and two points in time, tt and t+Tt+T), or one starting point (tt) and the average growth within the following nn years (t+1,t+2,...,t+nt+1, t+2, ..., t+n), respectively. Beta convergence can be calculated either in a linearized OLS regression model or in a nonlinear regression model. When no other variables are integrated in this model, it is called absolute beta convergence. Implementing other region-related variables (conditions) into the model leads to conditional beta convergence. If there is beta convergence (β<0\beta < 0), it is possible to calculate the speed of convergence, λ\lambda, and the so-called Half-Life HH, while the latter is the time taken to reduce the disparities by one half (Allington/McCombie 2007, Goecke/Huether 2016). There is sigma convergence, when the dispersion of the variable (σ\sigma), e.g. calculated as standard deviation or coefficient of variation, reduces from tt to t+Tt+T. This can be measured using ANOVA for two years or trend regression with respect to several years (Furceri 2005, Goecke/Huether 2016).

The rca function is a wrapper for the functions betaconv.ols, betaconv.nls, sigmaconv and sigmaconv.t. This function calculates (absolute and/or conditional) beta convergence and sigma convergence. Regional disparities are measured by the standard deviation (or variance, coefficient of variation) for all GDPs per capita (or another economic variable) for the given years. Beta convergence is estimated either using ordinary least squares (OLS) or nonlinear least squares (NLS). If the beta coefficient is negative (using OLS) or positive (using NLS), there is beta convergence. Sigma convergence is analyzed either using an analysis of variance (ANOVA) for these deviation measures (year 1 divided by year 2, F-statistic) or a trend regression (F-statistic, t-statistic). In the former case, if σt1/σt2>0\sigma_t1/\sigma_t2 > 0, there is sigma convergence. In the latter case, if the slope of the trend regression is negative, there is sigma convergence.

Value

A list containing the following objects:

betaconv

A list containing the following objects:

regdata

A data frame containing the regression data, including the lnln-transformed economic variables

tinterval

The time interval

abeta

A list containing the estimates of the absolute beta convergence regression model, including lambda and half-life

cbeta

If conditions are stated: a list containing the estimates of the conditional beta convergence regression model, including lambda and half-life

sigmaconv

A list containing the following objects:

sigmaconv

A matrix containing either the standard deviations, their quotient and the results of the significance test (F-statistic) or the results of trend regression

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Allington, N. F. B./McCombie, J. S. L. (2007): “Economic growth and beta-convergence in the East European Transition Economies”. In: Arestis, P./Baddely, M./McCombie, J. S. L. (eds.): Economic Growth. New Directions in Theory and Policy. Cheltenham: Elgar. p. 200-222.

Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (2009): “Introduction: regional growth and development theories in the twenty-first century - recent theoretical advances and future challenges”. In: Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (eds.): Handbook of Regional Growth and Development Theories. Cheltenham: Elgar. p. 1-16.

Dapena, A. D./Vazquez, E. F./Morollon, F. R. (2016): “The role of spatial scale in regional convergence: the effect of MAUP in the estimation of beta-convergence equations”. In: The Annals of Regional Science, 56, 2, p. 473-489.

Furceri, D. (2005): “Beta and sigma-convergence: A mathematical relation of causality”. In: Economics Letters, 89, 2, p. 212-215.

Goecke, H./Huether, M. (2016): “Regional Convergence in Europe”. In: Intereconomics, 51, 3, p. 165-171.

Young, A. T./Higgins, M. J./Levy, D. (2008): “Sigma Convergence versus Beta Convergence: Evidence from U.S. County-Level Data”. In: Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 40, 5, p. 1083-1093.

See Also

betaconv.ols, betaconv.nls, betaconv.speed, sigmaconv, sigmaconv.t, cv, sd2, var2

Examples

data (G.counties.gdp)
# Loading GDP data for Germany (counties = Landkreise)

rca (G.counties.gdp$gdppc2010, 2010, G.counties.gdp$gdppc2011, 2011, 
conditions = NULL, beta.plot = TRUE)
# Two years, no conditions (Absolute beta convergence)


regionaldummies <- to.dummy(G.counties.gdp$regional)
# Creating dummy variables for West/East
G.counties.gdp$West <- regionaldummies[,2]
G.counties.gdp$East <- regionaldummies[,1]
# Adding dummy variables to data

rca (G.counties.gdp$gdppc2010, 2010, G.counties.gdp$gdppc2011, 2011, 
conditions = G.counties.gdp[c(70,71)])
# Two years, with conditions
# (Absolute and conditional beta convergence)

converg1 <- rca (G.counties.gdp$gdppc2010, 2010, G.counties.gdp$gdppc2011, 2011, 
conditions = G.counties.gdp[c(70,71)])
# Store results in object
converg1$betaconv$abeta
# Addressing estimates for the conditional beta model


rca (G.counties.gdp$gdppc2010, 2010, G.counties.gdp[65:68], 2014, conditions = NULL, 
sigma.type = "trend", beta.plot = TRUE, sigma.plot = TRUE)
# Five years, no conditions (Absolute beta convergence)
# with plots for both beta and sigma convergence

Law of retail gravitation by Reilly

Description

Calculating the proportion of sales from an intermediate town between two cities or retail locations

Usage

reilly(P_a, P_b, D_a, D_b, gamma = 1, lambda = 2, relation = NULL)

Arguments

P_a

a single numeric value of attractivity/population size of location/city aa

P_b

a single numeric value of attractivity/population size of location/city bb

D_a

a single numeric value of the distance from the intermediate town to location/city aa

D_b

a single numeric value of the distance from the intermediate town to location/city bb

gamma

a single numeric value for the exponential weighting of size (default: 1)

lambda

a single numeric value for the exponential weighting of distance (transport costs, default: -2)

relation

a single numeric value containing the relation of trade between cities/locations aa and bb (only needed if the distance decay parameters has to be estimated instead of the sales flows)

Details

The law of retail gravitation by Reilly (1929, 1931) was the first spatial interaction model for retailing and services. This "law" states that two cities/locations attract customers from an intermediate town proportionally to the attractivity/population size of the two cities/locations and in inverse proportion to the squares of the transport costs (e.g. distance, travelling time) from these two locations to the intermediate town. But both variables can be weighted by exponents. The distance exponent can also be derived from empirical data (if an empirical relation is stated). The breaking point formula by Converse (1949) is a separate transformation of Reilly's law (see the function converse). The models by Reilly and Converse are simple spatial interaction models and are considered as deterministic market area models due to their exact allocation of demand origins to locations. A probabilistic approach including a theoretical framework was developed by Huff (1962) (see the function huff).

Value

If no relation is stated, a list with three values:

relation_AB

relation of trade between cities/locations aa and bb

prop_A

proportion of city/location aa

prop_B

proportion of city/location bb

If a relation is stated instead of weighting parameters, a single numeric value containing the estimated distance decay parameter.

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Berman, B. R./Evans, J. R. (2012): “Retail Management: A Strategic Approach”. 12th edition. Bosten : Pearson.

Converse, P. D. (1949): “New Laws of Retail Gravitation”. In: Journal of Marketing, 14, 3, p. 379-384.

Huff, D. L. (1962): “Determination of Intra-Urban Retail Trade Areas”. Los Angeles : University of California.

Levy, M./Weitz, B. A. (2012): “Retailing management”. 8th edition. New York : McGraw-Hill Irwin.

Loeffler, G. (1998): “Market areas - a methodological reflection on their boundaries”. In: GeoJournal, 45, 4, p. 265-272

Reilly, W. J. (1929): “Methods for the Study of Retail Relationships”. Studies in Marketing, 4. Austin : Bureau of Business Research, The University of Texas.

Reilly, W. J. (1931): “The Law of Retail Gravitation”. New York.

See Also

huff, converse

Examples

# Example from Converse (1949):
reilly (39851, 37366, 27, 25)
# two cities (pop. size 39.851 and 37.366) 
# with distances of 27 and 25 miles to intermediate town
myresults <- reilly (39851, 37366, 27, 25)
myresults$prop_A
# proportion of location a
# Distance decay parameter for the given sales relation:
reilly (39851, 37366, 27, 25, gamma = 1, lambda = NULL, relation = 0.9143555)   
# returns 2

Ripley's K

Description

Analyzing point clustering with Ripley's K function

Usage

ripley(loc_df, loc_id, loc_lat, loc_lon, 
area, t.max, t.sep = 10, K.local = FALSE, 
ci.boot = FALSE, ci.alpha = 0.05, ciboot.samples = 100,
progmsg = FALSE, K.plot = TRUE, Kplot.func = "K",
plot.title = "Ripley's K", plotX = "t", 
plotY = paste(Kplot.func, "Observed vs. expected"), 
lcol.exp = "blue", lcol.emp = "red", lsize.exp = 1, 
ltype.exp = "solid", lsize.emp = 1, ltype.emp = "solid",
bg.col = "gray95", bgrid = TRUE, bgrid.col = "white", 
bgrid.size = 2, bgrid.type = "solid")

Arguments

loc_df

A data frame containing the points

loc_id

Column containing the IDs of the points in the data frame loc_df

loc_lat

Column containing the latitudes of the points in the data frame loc_df

loc_lon

Column containing the longitudes of the points in the data frame loc_df

area

Total area of the regarded region

t.max

Maximum distance

t.sep

Number of distance intervals

K.local

Logical arguments that indicates whether local K values are computed or not

ci.boot

Logical arguments that indicates whether bootstrap confidence intervals are computed or not

ci.alpha

Significance level of the bootstrap confidence intervals

ciboot.samples

No. of bootstrap samples

progmsg

Logical argument: Printing progress messages or not

K.plot

Logical argument: Plot K function or not

Kplot.func

Which function has to be plotted? K function (Kplot.func = "K"), L function (Kplot.func = "L") or H function (Kplot.func = "H")

plot.title

If K.plot = TRUE: Plot title

plotX

If K.plot = TRUE: name of the X axis

plotY

If K.plot = TRUE: name of the Y axis

lcol.exp

If K.plot = TRUE: color of the line representing the expected values

lcol.emp

If K.plot = TRUE: color of the line representing the empirical values

lsize.exp

If K.plot = TRUE: size of the line representing the expected values

lsize.emp

If K.plot = TRUE: size of the line representing the empirical values

ltype.exp

If K.plot = TRUE: type of the line representing the expected values

ltype.emp

If K.plot = TRUE: type of the line representing the empirical values

bg.col

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), bg.col defines the background color of the plot (default: "gray95")

bgrid

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve), the logical argument bgrid defines if a grid is shown in the plot

bgrid.col

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve) and bgrid = TRUE (background grid), bgrid.col defines the color of the background grid (default: "white")

bgrid.size

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve) and bgrid = TRUE (background grid), bgrid.size defines the size of the background grid (default: 2)

bgrid.type

if lc = TRUE (plot of Lorenz curve) and bgrid = TRUE (background grid), bgrid.type defines the type of lines of the background grid (default: "solid")

Details

Calculating and plotting of the K function and its derivations (L function, H function) and, optionally, bootstrap confidence intervals.

Value

The function returns a list containing:

K

A data.frame containing the K/L/H/t values

K_local

A data.frame containing the local K values (if stated)

local_ci

A data.frame containing the local confidence intervals (if stated)

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Kiskowski, M.A./Hancock, J. F./Kenworthy, A. (2009): “On the Use of Ripley's K-function and its Derivatives to Analyze Domain Size”. In: Biophysical Journal, 97, 4, p. 1095-1103.

Krider, R. E./Putler, R. S. (2013): “Which Birds of a Feather Flock Together? Clustering and Avoidance Patterns of Similar Retail Outlets”. In: Geographical Analysis, 45, 2, p. 123-149.

See Also

dist, dist.buf, dist.mat

Examples

## Not run: 
data(GoettingenHealth1)
# general practitioners, psychotherapists and pharmacies

area_goe <- 1753000000
# area of Landkreis Goettingen (sqm)
area_nom <- 1267000000
# area of Landkreis Northeim (sqm)
area_gn <- area_goe+area_nom
sqrt(area_gn/pi)

# this takes some seconds
ripley(GoettingenHealth1[GoettingenHealth1$type == "phys_gen",], 
"location", "lat", "lon", area = area_gn, t.max = 30000, t.sep = 300)

ripley(GoettingenHealth1[GoettingenHealth1$type == "pharm",], 
"location", "lat", "lon", area = area_gn, t.max = 30000, t.sep = 300)

ripley(GoettingenHealth1[GoettingenHealth1$type == "psych",], 
"location", "lat", "lon", area = area_gn, t.max = 30000, t.sep = 300)

## End(Not run)

Standard deviation (extended)

Description

Calculating the standard deviation (sd), weighted or non-weighted, for samples or populations

Usage

sd2 (x, is.sample = TRUE, weighting = NULL, wmean = FALSE, na.rm = TRUE)

Arguments

x

a numeric vector

is.sample

logical argument that indicates if the dataset is a sample or the population (default: is.sample = TRUE, so the denominator of variance is n1n-1)

weighting

a numeric vector containing weighting data to compute the weighted standard deviation (instead of the non-weighted sd)

wmean

logical argument that indicates if the weighted mean is used when calculating the weighted standard deviation

na.rm

logical argument that whether NA values should be extracted or not

Details

The function calculates the standard deviation. Unlike the R base sd function, the sd2 function allows to choose if the data is treated as sample (denominator of variance is n1n-1)) or not (denominator of variance is nn))

From a regional economic perspective, the sd is closely linked to the concept of sigma convergence (σ\sigma) which means a harmonization of regional economic output or income over time, while the other type of convergence, beta convergence (β\beta), means a decline of dispersion because poor regions have a stronger growth than rich regions (Capello/Nijkamp 2009). The sd allows to summarize regional disparities (e.g. disparities in regional GDP per capita) in one indicator. The coefficient of variation (see the function cv) is more frequently used for this purpose (e.g. Lessmann 2005, Huang/Leung 2009, Siljak 2015). But the sd can also be used for any other types of disparities or dispersion, such as disparities in supply (e.g. density of physicians or grocery stores).

The standard deviation can be weighted by using a second weighting vector. As there is more than one way to weight measures of statistical dispersion, this function uses the formula for the weighted sd (σw\sigma_w) from Sheret (1984). The vector x is automatically treated as a sample (such as in the base sd function), so the denominator of variance is n1n-1, if it is not, set is.sample = FALSE.

Value

Single numeric value. If weighting is specified, the function returns a weighted standard deviation (optionally using a weighted arithmetic mean if wmean = TRUE).

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Bahrenberg, G./Giese, E./Mevenkamp, N./Nipper, J. (2010): “Statistische Methoden in der Geographie. Band 1: Univariate und bivariate Statistik”. Stuttgart: Borntraeger.

Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (2009): “Introduction: regional growth and development theories in the twenty-first century - recent theoretical advances and future challenges”. In: Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (eds.): Handbook of Regional Growth and Development Theories. Cheltenham: Elgar. p. 1-16.

Lessmann, C. (2005): “Regionale Disparitaeten in Deutschland und ausgesuchten OECD-Staaten im Vergleich”. ifo Dresden berichtet, 3/2005. https://www.ifo.de/DocDL/ifodb_2005_3_25-33.pdf.

Huang, Y./Leung, Y. (2009): “Measuring Regional Inequality: A Comparison of Coefficient of Variation and Hoover Concentration Index”. In: The Open Geography Journal, 2, p. 25-34.

Sheret, M. (1984): “The Coefficient of Variation: Weighting Considerations”. In: Social Indicators Research, 15, 3, p. 289-295.

Siljak, D. (2015): “Real Economic Convergence in Western Europe from 1995 to 2013”. In: International Journal of Business and Economic Development, 3, 3, p. 56-67.

See Also

gini, herf, hoover, mean2, rca

Examples

# Regional disparities / sigma convergence in Germany
data(G.counties.gdp)
# GDP per capita for German counties (Landkreise)
sd_gdppc <- apply (G.counties.gdp[54:68], MARGIN = 2, FUN = sd2)
# Calculating standard deviation for the years 2000-2014
years <- 2000:2014
# vector of years (2000-2014)
plot(years, sd_gdppc, "l", ylim = c(0,15000), xlab = "Year", 
ylab = "SD of GDP per capita")
# Plot sd over time

Shift-share analysis

Description

Analyzing regional growth with the shift-share analysis

Usage

shift(e_ij1, e_ij2, e_i1, e_i2, industry.names = NULL, 
shift.method = "Dunn", print.results = TRUE, plot.results = FALSE, 
plot.colours = NULL, plot.title = NULL, plot.portfolio = FALSE, ...)

Arguments

e_ij1

a numeric vector with ii values containing the employment in ii industries in region jj at time 1

e_ij2

a numeric vector with ii values containing the employment in ii industries in region jj at time 2

e_i1

a numeric vector with ii values containing the total employment in ii industries at time 1

e_i2

a numeric vector with ii values containing the total employment in ii industries at time 2

industry.names

Industry names (e.g. from the relevant statistical classification of economic activities)

shift.method

Method of shift-share-analysis to be used ("Dunn", "Esteban", "Gerfin") (default: shift.method = "Dunn")

print.results

Logical argument that indicates if the function shows the results or not

plot.results

Logical argument that indicates if the results have to be plotted

plot.colours

If plot.results = TRUE: Plot colours

plot.title

If plot.results = TRUE: Plot title

plot.portfolio

Logical argument that indicates if the results have to be plotted in a portfolio matrix additionally

...

Additional arguments for the portfolio plot (see the function portfolio)

Details

The shift-share analysis (Dunn 1960) adresses the regional growth (or decline) regarding the over-all development in the national economy. The aim of this analysis model is to identify which parts of the regional economic development can be traced back to national trends, effects of the regional industry structure and (positive) regional factors. The growth (or decline) of regional employment consists of three factors: lt+1lt=nps+nds+ntsl_{t+1}-l_t = nps + nds + nts, where ll is the employment in the region at time tt and t+1t+1, respectively, and npsnps is the net proportionality shift, ndsnds is the net differential shift and ntsnts is the net total shift. Other variants are e.g. the shift-share method by Gerfin (Index method), the dynamic shift-share analysis (Barff/Knight 1988) or the extension by Esteban-Marquillas (1972).

As there is more than one way to calculate a Dunn-type shift-share analysis and the terms are not used consequently in the regional economic literature, this function and the documentation use the formulae and terms given in Farhauer/Kroell (2013). If shift.method = "Dunn", this function calculates the net proportionality shift (npsnps), the net differential shift (ndsnds) and the net total shift (ntsnts) where the last one represents the residuum of (positive) regional factors.

This function calculates a shift-share analysis for two years.

Value

A list containing the following objects:

components

A matrix containing the shift-share components related to the chosen method

growth

A matrix containing the industry-specific growth values

method

The chosen method, e.g. "Dunn"

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Arcelus, F. J. (1984): “An Extension of Shift-Share Analysis”. In: In: Growth and Change, 15, 1, p. 3-8.

Barff, R. A./Knight, P. L. (1988): “Dynamic Shift-Share Analysis”. In: Growth and Change, 19, 2, p. 1-10.

Casler, S. D. (1989): “A Theoretical Context for Shift and Share Analysis”. In: Regional Studies, 23, 1, p. 43-48.

Dunn, E. S. Jr. (1960): “A statistical and analytical technique for regional analysis”. In: Papers and Proceedings of the Regional Science Association, 6, p. 97-112.

Esteban-Marquillas, J. M. (1972): “Shift- and share analysis revisited”. In: Regional and Urban Economics, 2, 3, p. 249-261.

Farhauer, O./Kroell, A. (2013): “Standorttheorien: Regional- und Stadtoekonomik in Theorie und Praxis”. Wiesbaden : Springer.

Gerfin, H. (1964): “Gesamtwirtschaftliches Wachstum und regionale Entwicklung”. In: Kyklos, 17, 4, p. 565-593.

Schoenebeck, C. (1996): “Wirtschaftsstruktur und Regionalentwicklung: Theoretische und empirische Befunde fuer die Bundesrepublik Deutschland”. Dortmunder Beitraege zur Raumplanung, 75. Dortmund.

See Also

portfolio, shiftd, shifti, , shift.growth

Examples

# Example from Farhauer/Kroell (2013):
region_A_t <- c(90,20,10,60)
region_A_t1 <- c(100,40,10,55)
# data for region A (time t and t+1)
nation_X_t <- c(400,150,150,400)
nation_X_t1 <- c(440,210,135,480)
# data for the national economy (time t and t+1)
resultsA <- shift(region_A_t, region_A_t1, nation_X_t, nation_X_t1)
# results for region A
region_B_t <- c(60,30,30,40)
region_B_t1 <- c(85,55,40,35)
# data for region B (time t and t+1)
resultsB <- shift(region_B_t, region_B_t1, nation_X_t, nation_X_t1)
# results for region B
region_C_t <- c(250,100,110,300)
region_C_t1 <- c(255,115,85,390)
# data for region C (time t and t+1)
resultsC <- shift(region_C_t, region_C_t1, nation_X_t, nation_X_t1)
# results for region C

# Example Freiburg dataset
data(Freiburg)
# Loads the data
shift(Freiburg$e_Freiburg2008, Freiburg$e_Freiburg2014, Freiburg$e_Germany2008, 
Freiburg$e_Germany2014)
# results for Freiburg and Germany (2008 vs. 2014)

Growth rates for shift-share analysis

Description

This function calculates industry-specific growth rates which are part of the shift-share analysis

Usage

shift.growth(e_ij1, e_ij2, e_i1, e_i2, time.periods = NULL, 
industry.names = NULL)

Arguments

e_ij1

a numeric vector with ii values containing the employment in ii industries in region jj at time 1

e_ij2

a numeric vector with ii values containing the employment in ii industries in region jj at time 2

e_i1

a numeric vector with ii values containing the total employment in ii industries at time 1

e_i2

a numeric vector with ii values containing the total employment in ii industries at time 2

time.periods

No. of regarded time periods (for average growth rates)

industry.names

Industry names (e.g. from the relevant statistical classification of economic activities)

Details

The shift-share analysis (Dunn 1960) adresses the regional growth (or decline) regarding the over-all development in the national economy. The aim of this analysis model is to identify which parts of the regional economic development can be traced back to national trends, effects of the regional industry structure and (positive) regional factors. The growth (or decline) of regional employment consists of three factors: lt+1lt=nps+nds+ntsl_{t+1}-l_t = nps + nds + nts, where ll is the employment in the region at time tt and t+1t+1, respectively, and npsnps is the net proportionality shift, ndsnds is the net differential shift and ntsnts is the net total shift. Other variants are e.g. the shift-share method by Gerfin (Index method) and the dynamic shift-share analysis (Barff/Knight 1988).

As there is more than one way to calculate a Dunn-type shift-share analysis and the terms are not used consequently in the regional economic literature, this function and the documentation use the formulae and terms given in Farhauer/Kroell (2013). If shift.method = "Dunn", this function calculates the net proportionality shift (npsnps), the net differential shift (ndsnds) and the net total shift (ntsnts) where the last one represents the residuum of (positive) regional factors.

This function calculates industry-specific growth rates which are part of a shift-share analysis.

Value

A matrix containing the industry-specific growth values

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Arcelus, F. J. (1984): “An Extension of Shift-Share Analysis”. In: In: Growth and Change, 15, 1, p. 3-8.

Barff, R. A./Knight, P. L. (1988): “Dynamic Shift-Share Analysis”. In: Growth and Change, 19, 2, p. 1-10.

Casler, S. D. (1989): “A Theoretical Context for Shift and Share Analysis”. In: Regional Studies, 23, 1, p. 43-48.

Dunn, E. S. Jr. (1960): “A statistical and analytical technique for regional analysis”. In: Papers and Proceedings of the Regional Science Association, 6, p. 97-112.

Esteban-Marquillas, J. M. (1972): “Shift- and share analysis revisited”. In: Regional and Urban Economics, 2, 3, p. 249-261.

Farhauer, O./Kroell, A. (2013): “Standorttheorien: Regional- und Stadtoekonomik in Theorie und Praxis”. Wiesbaden : Springer.

Gerfin, H. (1964): “Gesamtwirtschaftliches Wachstum und regionale Entwicklung”. In: Kyklos, 17, 4, p. 565-593.

Goschin, Z. (2014): “Regional growth in Romania after its accession to EU: a shift-share analysis approach”. In: Procedia Economics and Finance, 15, p. 169-175.

Schoenebeck, C. (1996): “Wirtschaftsstruktur und Regionalentwicklung: Theoretische und empirische Befunde fuer die Bundesrepublik Deutschland”. Dortmunder Beitraege zur Raumplanung, 75. Dortmund.

See Also

portfolio, shift, shiftd, shifti

Examples

# Example from Farhauer/Kroell (2013):
region_A_t <- c(90,20,10,60)
region_A_t1 <- c(100,40,10,55)
# data for region A (time t and t+1)
nation_X_t <- c(400,150,150,400)
nation_X_t1 <- c(440,210,135,480)
# data for the national economy (time t and t+1)
shift.growth(region_A_t, region_A_t1, nation_X_t, nation_X_t1)

Dynamic shift-share analysis

Description

Analyzing regional growth with the dynamic shift-share analysis

Usage

shiftd(e_ij1, e_ij2, e_i1, e_i2, time1, time2, 
industry.names = NULL, shift.method = "Dunn", 
gerfin.shifts = "mean", print.results = TRUE, 
plot.results = FALSE, plot.colours = NULL, plot.title = NULL, 
plot.portfolio = FALSE, ...)

Arguments

e_ij1

a numeric vector with ii values containing the employment in ii industries in region jj at time 1

e_ij2

a numeric data frame or matrix with ii rows containing the employment in ii industries in region jj and tt columns, representing tt (t>1t > 1) years

e_i1

a numeric vector with ii values containing the total employment in ii industries at time 1

e_i2

a numeric data frame or matrix with ii rows containing the total employment in ii industries and tt columns, representing tt (t>1t > 1) years

time1

Initial year

time2

Final year

industry.names

Industry names (e.g. from the relevant statistical classification of economic activities)

shift.method

Method of shift-share-analysis to be used ("Dunn", "Gerfin") (default: shift.method = "Dunn")

gerfin.shifts

If shift.method = "Gerfin": Logical argument that indicates if the shifts are calculated as sums or as means (default: gerfin = "mean")

print.results

Logical argument that indicates if the function shows the results or not

plot.results

Logical argument that indicates if the results have to be plotted

plot.colours

If plot.results = TRUE: Plot colours

plot.title

If plot.results = TRUE: Plot title

plot.portfolio

Logical argument that indicates if the results have to be plotted in a portfolio matrix additionally

...

Additional arguments for the portfolio plot (see the function portfolio)

Details

The shift-share analysis (Dunn 1960) adresses the regional growth (or decline) regarding the over-all development in the national economy. The aim of this analysis model is to identify which parts of the regional economic development can be traced back to national trends, effects of the regional industry structure and (positive) regional factors. The growth (or decline) of regional employment consists of three factors: lt+1lt=nps+nds+ntsl_{t+1}-l_t = nps + nds + nts, where ll is the employment in the region at time tt and t+1t+1, respectively, and npsnps is the net proportionality shift, ndsnds is the net differential shift and ntsnts is the net total shift. Other variants are e.g. the shift-share method by Gerfin (Index method) and the dynamic shift-share analysis (Barff/Knight 1988).

As there is more than one way to calculate a Dunn-type shift-share analysis and the terms are not used consequently in the regional economic literature, this function and the documentation use the formulae and terms given in Farhauer/Kroell (2013). If shift.method = "Dunn", this function calculates the net proportionality shift (npsnps), the net differential shift (ndsnds) and the net total shift (ntsnts) where the last one represents the residuum of (positive) regional factors.

This function calculates a dynamic shift-share analysis for at least two years.

Value

A list containing the following objects:

components

A matrix containing the shift-share components related to the chosen method

components.year

A matrix containing the shift-share components for each year

growth

A matrix containing the industry-specific growth values

method

The chosen method, e.g. "Dunn"

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Arcelus, F. J. (1984): “An Extension of Shift-Share Analysis”. In: In: Growth and Change, 15, 1, p. 3-8.

Barff, R. A./Knight, P. L. (1988): “Dynamic Shift-Share Analysis”. In: Growth and Change, 19, 2, p. 1-10.

Casler, S. D. (1989): “A Theoretical Context for Shift and Share Analysis”. In: Regional Studies, 23, 1, p. 43-48.

Dunn, E. S. Jr. (1960): “A statistical and analytical technique for regional analysis”. In: Papers and Proceedings of the Regional Science Association, 6, p. 97-112.

Esteban-Marquillas, J. M. (1972): “Shift- and share analysis revisited”. In: Regional and Urban Economics, 2, 3, p. 249-261.

Farhauer, O./Kroell, A. (2013): “Standorttheorien: Regional- und Stadtoekonomik in Theorie und Praxis”. Wiesbaden : Springer.

Gerfin, H. (1964): “Gesamtwirtschaftliches Wachstum und regionale Entwicklung”. In: Kyklos, 17, 4, p. 565-593.

Schoenebeck, C. (1996): “Wirtschaftsstruktur und Regionalentwicklung: Theoretische und empirische Befunde fuer die Bundesrepublik Deutschland”. Dortmunder Beitraege zur Raumplanung, 75. Dortmund.

See Also

portfolio, shift, shifti, shift.growth

Examples

# Example from Farhauer/Kroell (2013), extended:
region_A_t <- c(90,20,10,60)
region_A_t1 <- c(100,40,10,55)
region_A_t2 <- c(105,45,15,60)
# data for region A (time t and t+1)
nation_X_t <- c(400,150,150,400)
nation_X_t1 <- c(440,210,135,480)
nation_X_t2 <- c(460,230,155,500)
# data for the national economy (time t and t+1)
shiftd(region_A_t, data.frame(region_A_t1, region_A_t2), nation_X_t, 
data.frame(nation_X_t1, nation_X_t2), time1 = 2000, time2 = 2002,
plot.results = TRUE, plot.portfolio = TRUE, psize = region_A_t1)

data(Goettingen)
shiftd(Goettingen$Goettingen2008[2:16], Goettingen[2:16,3:11], 
Goettingen$BRD2008[2:16], Goettingen[2:16,13:21],
time1 = 2008, time2 = 2017, industry.names = Goettingen$WA_WZ2008[2:16], 
shift.method = "Dunn")

Shift-share analysis for industries

Description

Analyzing industry-specific regional growth with the shift-share analysis

Usage

shifti(e_ij1, e_ij2, e_i1, e_i2, industry.names = NULL, 
shift.method = "Dunn", print.results = TRUE, plot.results = FALSE, 
plot.colours = NULL, plot.title = NULL, plot.portfolio = FALSE, ...)

Arguments

e_ij1

a numeric vector with ii values containing the employment in ii industries in region jj at time 1

e_ij2

a numeric vector with ii values containing the employment in ii industries in region jj at time 2

e_i1

a numeric vector with ii values containing the total employment in ii industries at time 1

e_i2

a numeric vector with ii values containing the total employment in ii industries at time 2

industry.names

Industry names (e.g. from the relevant statistical classification of economic activities)

shift.method

Method of shift-share-analysis to be used ("Dunn", "Gerfin") (default: shift.method = "Dunn")

print.results

Logical argument that indicates if the function shows the results or not

plot.results

Logical argument that indicates if the results have to be plotted

plot.colours

If plot.results = TRUE: Plot colours

plot.title

If plot.results = TRUE: Plot title

plot.portfolio

Logical argument that indicates if the results have to be plotted in a portfolio matrix additionally

...

Additional arguments for the portfolio plot (see the function portfolio)

Details

The shift-share analysis (Dunn 1960) adresses the regional growth (or decline) regarding the over-all development in the national economy. The aim of this analysis model is to identify which parts of the regional economic development can be traced back to national trends, effects of the regional industry structure and (positive) regional factors. The growth (or decline) of regional employment consists of three factors: lt+1lt=nps+nds+ntsl_{t+1}-l_t = nps + nds + nts, where ll is the employment in the region at time tt and t+1t+1, respectively, and npsnps is the net proportionality shift, ndsnds is the net differential shift and ntsnts is the net total shift. Other variants are e.g. the shift-share method by Gerfin (Index method) and the dynamic shift-share analysis (Barff/Knight 1988).

As there is more than one way to calculate a Dunn-type shift-share analysis and the terms are not used consequently in the regional economic literature, this function and the documentation use the formulae and terms given in Farhauer/Kroell (2013). If shift.method = "Dunn", this function calculates the net proportionality shift (npsnps), the net differential shift (ndsnds) and the net total shift (ntsnts) where the last one represents the residuum of (positive) regional factors.

This function calculates a shift-share analysis for at least two years and results industry-specific shift-share components.

Value

A list containing the following objects:

components

A matrix containing the shift-share components related to the chosen method

components.industry

A matrix containing the shift-share components for each industry

growth

A matrix containing the industry-specific growth values

method

The chosen method, e.g. "Dunn"

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Arcelus, F. J. (1984): “An Extension of Shift-Share Analysis”. In: In: Growth and Change, 15, 1, p. 3-8.

Barff, R. A./Knight, P. L. (1988): “Dynamic Shift-Share Analysis”. In: Growth and Change, 19, 2, p. 1-10.

Casler, S. D. (1989): “A Theoretical Context for Shift and Share Analysis”. In: Regional Studies, 23, 1, p. 43-48.

Dunn, E. S. Jr. (1960): “A statistical and analytical technique for regional analysis”. In: Papers and Proceedings of the Regional Science Association, 6, p. 97-112.

Esteban-Marquillas, J. M. (1972): “Shift- and share analysis revisited”. In: Regional and Urban Economics, 2, 3, p. 249-261.

Farhauer, O./Kroell, A. (2013): “Standorttheorien: Regional- und Stadtoekonomik in Theorie und Praxis”. Wiesbaden : Springer.

Gerfin, H. (1964): “Gesamtwirtschaftliches Wachstum und regionale Entwicklung”. In: Kyklos, 17, 4, p. 565-593.

Schoenebeck, C. (1996): “Wirtschaftsstruktur und Regionalentwicklung: Theoretische und empirische Befunde fuer die Bundesrepublik Deutschland”. Dortmunder Beitraege zur Raumplanung, 75. Dortmund.

See Also

portfolio, shift, shifti, shift.growth

Examples

# Example from Farhauer/Kroell (2013):
region_A_t <- c(90,20,10,60)
region_A_t1 <- c(100,40,10,55)
# data for region A (time t and t+1)
nation_X_t <- c(400,150,150,400)
nation_X_t1 <- c(440,210,135,480)
# data for the national economy (time t and t+1)
shifti(region_A_t, region_A_t1, nation_X_t, nation_X_t1,
plot.results = TRUE, plot.portfolio = TRUE, psize = region_A_t1)

Dynamic shift-share analysis for industries

Description

Analyzing industry-specific regional growth with the dynamic shift-share analysis

Usage

shiftid(e_ij1, e_ij2, e_i1, e_i2, time1, time2, 
industry.names = NULL, shift.method = "Dunn", 
gerfin.shifts = "mean", print.results = TRUE, 
plot.results = FALSE, plot.colours = NULL, plot.title = NULL, 
plot.portfolio = FALSE, ...)

Arguments

e_ij1

a numeric vector with ii values containing the employment in ii industries in region jj at time 1

e_ij2

a numeric data frame or matrix with ii rows containing the employment in ii industries in region jj and tt columns, representing tt (t>1t > 1) years

e_i1

a numeric vector with ii values containing the total employment in ii industries at time 1

e_i2

a numeric data frame or matrix with ii rows containing the total employment in ii industries and tt columns, representing tt (t>1t > 1) years

time1

Initial year

time2

Final year

industry.names

Industry names (e.g. from the relevant statistical classification of economic activities)

shift.method

Method of shift-share-analysis to be used ("Dunn", "Gerfin") (default: shift.method = "Dunn")

gerfin.shifts

If shift.method = "Gerfin": Logical argument that indicates if the shifts are calculated as sums or as means (default: gerfin = "mean")

print.results

Logical argument that indicates if the function shows the results or not

plot.results

Logical argument that indicates if the results have to be plotted

plot.colours

If plot.results = TRUE: Plot colours

plot.title

If plot.results = TRUE: Plot title

plot.portfolio

Logical argument that indicates if the results have to be plotted in a portfolio matrix additionally

...

Additional arguments for the portfolio plot (see the function portfolio)

Details

The shift-share analysis (Dunn 1960) adresses the regional growth (or decline) regarding the over-all development in the national economy. The aim of this analysis model is to identify which parts of the regional economic development can be traced back to national trends, effects of the regional industry structure and (positive) regional factors. The growth (or decline) of regional employment consists of three factors: lt+1lt=nps+nds+ntsl_{t+1}-l_t = nps + nds + nts, where ll is the employment in the region at time tt and t+1t+1, respectively, and npsnps is the net proportionality shift, ndsnds is the net differential shift and ntsnts is the net total shift. Other variants are e.g. the shift-share method by Gerfin (Index method) and the dynamic shift-share analysis (Barff/Knight 1988).

As there is more than one way to calculate a Dunn-type shift-share analysis and the terms are not used consequently in the regional economic literature, this function and the documentation use the formulae and terms given in Farhauer/Kroell (2013). If shift.method = "Dunn", this function calculates the net proportionality shift (npsnps), the net differential shift (ndsnds) and the net total shift (ntsnts) where the last one represents the residuum of (positive) regional factors.

This function calculates a dynamic shift-share analysis for at least two years.

Value

A list containing the following objects:

components

A matrix containing the shift-share components related to the chosen method

components.year

A matrix containing the shift-share components for each year

growth

A matrix containing the industry-specific growth values

method

The chosen method, e.g. "Dunn"

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Arcelus, F. J. (1984): “An Extension of Shift-Share Analysis”. In: In: Growth and Change, 15, 1, p. 3-8.

Barff, R. A./Knight, P. L. (1988): “Dynamic Shift-Share Analysis”. In: Growth and Change, 19, 2, p. 1-10.

Casler, S. D. (1989): “A Theoretical Context for Shift and Share Analysis”. In: Regional Studies, 23, 1, p. 43-48.

Dunn, E. S. Jr. (1960): “A statistical and analytical technique for regional analysis”. In: Papers and Proceedings of the Regional Science Association, 6, p. 97-112.

Esteban-Marquillas, J. M. (1972): “Shift- and share analysis revisited”. In: Regional and Urban Economics, 2, 3, p. 249-261.

Farhauer, O./Kroell, A. (2013): “Standorttheorien: Regional- und Stadtoekonomik in Theorie und Praxis”. Wiesbaden : Springer.

Gerfin, H. (1964): “Gesamtwirtschaftliches Wachstum und regionale Entwicklung”. In: Kyklos, 17, 4, p. 565-593.

Schoenebeck, C. (1996): “Wirtschaftsstruktur und Regionalentwicklung: Theoretische und empirische Befunde fuer die Bundesrepublik Deutschland”. Dortmunder Beitraege zur Raumplanung, 75. Dortmund.

See Also

portfolio, shift, shifti, shift.growth

Examples

# Example from Farhauer/Kroell (2013), extended:
region_A_t <- c(90,20,10,60)
region_A_t1 <- c(100,40,10,55)
region_A_t2 <- c(105,45,15,60)
# data for region A (time t and t+1)
nation_X_t <- c(400,150,150,400)
nation_X_t1 <- c(440,210,135,480)
nation_X_t2 <- c(460,230,155,500)
# data for the national economy (time t and t+1)
shiftd(region_A_t, data.frame(region_A_t1, region_A_t2), nation_X_t, 
data.frame(nation_X_t1, nation_X_t2), time1 = 2000, time2 = 2002,
plot.results = TRUE, plot.portfolio = TRUE, psize = region_A_t1)

data(Goettingen)
shiftid(Goettingen$Goettingen2008[2:16], Goettingen[2:16,3:11], 
Goettingen$BRD2008[2:16], Goettingen[2:16,13:21],
time1 = 2008, time2 = 2017, industry.names = Goettingen$WA_WZ2008[2:16], 
shift.method = "Dunn")

Shift-share prognosis

Description

Forecasting regional employment growth with the shift-share analysis (Gerfin model)

Usage

shiftp(e_ij1, e_ij2, e_i1, e_i2, e_i3, time1, time2, time3,
industry.names = NULL, print.results = TRUE, 
plot.results = FALSE, plot.colours = NULL, plot.title = NULL,
plot.portfolio = FALSE, ...)

Arguments

e_ij1

a numeric vector with ii values containing the employment in ii industries in region jj at time 1

e_ij2

a numeric vector with ii values containing the employment in ii industries in region jj at time 2

e_i1

a numeric vector with ii values containing the total employment in ii industries at time 1

e_i2

a numeric vector with ii values containing the total employment in ii industries at time 2

e_i3

a numeric vector with ii values containing the total employment in ii industries at time 3 (forecast value for total employment)

time1

start year (single value)

time2

end year of empirical employment data (single value)

time3

year of prognosis (single value)

industry.names

Industry names (e.g. from the relevant statistical classification of economic activities)

print.results

Logical argument that indicates if the function shows the results or not

plot.results

Logical argument that indicates if the results have to be plotted

plot.colours

If plot.results = TRUE: Plot colours

plot.title

If plot.results = TRUE: Plot title

plot.portfolio

Logical argument that indicates if the results have to be plotted in a portfolio matrix additionally

...

Additional arguments for the portfolio plot (see the function portfolio)

Details

The shift-share analysis (Dunn 1960) adresses the regional growth (or decline) regarding the over-all development in the national economy. The aim of this analysis model is to identify which parts of the regional economic development can be traced back to national trends, effects of the regional industry structure and (positive) regional factors. The growth (or decline) of regional employment consists of three factors: lt+1lt=nps+nds+ntsl_{t+1}-l_t = nps + nds + nts, where ll is the employment in the region at time tt and t+1t+1, respectively, and npsnps is the net proportionality shift, ndsnds is the net differential shift and ntsnts is the net total shift. Other variants are e.g. the shift-share method by Gerfin (Index method), the dynamic shift-share analysis (Barff/Knight 1988) or the extension by Esteban-Marquillas (1972).

As there is more than one way to calculate a Dunn-type shift-share analysis and the terms are not used consequently in the regional economic literature, this function and the documentation use the formulae and terms given in Farhauer/Kroell (2013). If shift.method = "Dunn", this function calculates the net proportionality shift (npsnps), the net differential shift (ndsnds) and the net total shift (ntsnts) where the last one represents the residuum of (positive) regional factors.

This function calculates an employment prognosis based on a Gerfin shift-share analysis for two years.

Value

A list containing the following objects:

components

A matrix containing the shift-share components related to the chosen method

growth

A matrix containing the industry-specific growth values

prog

A matrix containing the industry-specific prognosis values

method

The chosen method, e.g. "Dunn"

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Arcelus, F. J. (1984): “An Extension of Shift-Share Analysis”. In: In: Growth and Change, 15, 1, p. 3-8.

Barff, R. A./Knight, P. L. (1988): “Dynamic Shift-Share Analysis”. In: Growth and Change, 19, 2, p. 1-10.

Casler, S. D. (1989): “A Theoretical Context for Shift and Share Analysis”. In: Regional Studies, 23, 1, p. 43-48.

Dunn, E. S. Jr. (1960): “A statistical and analytical technique for regional analysis”. In: Papers and Proceedings of the Regional Science Association, 6, p. 97-112.

Esteban-Marquillas, J. M. (1972): “Shift- and share analysis revisited”. In: Regional and Urban Economics, 2, 3, p. 249-261.

Farhauer, O./Kroell, A. (2013): “Standorttheorien: Regional- und Stadtoekonomik in Theorie und Praxis”. Wiesbaden : Springer.

Gerfin, H. (1964): “Gesamtwirtschaftliches Wachstum und regionale Entwicklung”. In: Kyklos, 17, 4, p. 565-593.

Schoenebeck, C. (1996): “Wirtschaftsstruktur und Regionalentwicklung: Theoretische und empirische Befunde fuer die Bundesrepublik Deutschland”. Dortmunder Beitraege zur Raumplanung, 75. Dortmund.

Spiekermann, K./Wegener, M. (2008): “Modelle in der Raumplanung I. 4 - Input-Output-Modelle”. Power Point presentation. http://www.spiekermann-wegener.de/mir/pdf/MIR1_4_111108.pdf.

See Also

portfolio, shiftd, shifti, , shift.growth

Examples

# Example data from Spiekermann/Wegener 2008:
# two regions, two industries
region1_2000 <- c(1400, 3600)
region1_2006 <- c(1000, 4400)
region2_2000 <- c(1200, 1800)
region2_2006 <- c(1100, 3700)
region3_2000 <- c(1100, 900)
region3_2006 <- c(800, 1000)
# regional values
nation_2000 <- c(3700, 6300)
nation_2006 <- c(2900, 9100)
# national values
nation_2010 <- c(2500, 12500)
# national prognosis values

# Analysis for region 1:
shiftp(region1_2000, region1_2006, nation_2000,
nation_2006, e_i3 = nation_2010, 
time1 = 2000, time2 = 2006, time3 = 2010)
# Analysis for region 2:
shiftp(region2_2000, region2_2006, nation_2000, 
nation_2006, e_i3 = nation_2010, 
time1 = 2000, time2 = 2006, time3 = 2010)
# Analysis for region 3:
shiftp(region3_2000, region3_2006, nation_2000, 
nation_2006, e_i3 = nation_2010, 
time1 = 2000, time2 = 2006, time3 = 2010)

Analysis of regional sigma convergence for two years using ANOVA

Description

This function provides the analysis of regional economic sigma convergence (decline of deviation) for two years using ANOVA (Analysis of Variance)

Usage

sigmaconv(gdp1, time1, gdp2, time2, sigma.measure = "sd", 
sigma.log = TRUE, sigma.weighting = NULL, sigma.norm = FALSE, 
sigma.issample = FALSE, print.results = FALSE)

Arguments

gdp1

A numeric vector containing the GDP per capita (or another economic variable) at time t

time1

A single value of time t (= the initial year)

gdp2

A numeric vector containing the GDP per capita (or another economic variable) at time t+1

time2

A single value of time t+1

sigma.measure

argument that indicates how the sigma convergence should be measured. The default is output = "sd", which means that the standard deviation is used. If output = "var" or output = "cv", the variance or the coefficient of variation is used, respectively.

sigma.log

Logical argument. Per default (sigma.log = TRUE), also in the sigma convergence analysis, the economic variables are transformed by natural logarithm. If the original values should be used, state sigma.log = FALSE

sigma.weighting

If the measure of statistical dispersion in the sigma convergence analysis (coefficient of variation or standard deviation) should be weighted, a weighting vector has to be stated

sigma.norm

Logical argument that indicates if a normalized coefficient of variation should be used instead

sigma.issample

logical argument that indicates if the dataset is a sample or the population (default: is.sample = FALSE, so the denominator of variance is nn)

print.results

Logical argument that indicates if the function shows the results or not

Details

From the regional economic perspective (in particular the neoclassical growth theory), regional disparities are expected to decline. This convergence can have different meanings: Sigma convergence (σ\sigma) means a harmonization of regional economic output or income over time, while beta convergence (β\beta) means a decline of dispersion because poor regions have a stronger economic growth than rich regions (Capello/Nijkamp 2009). Regardless of the theoretical assumptions of a harmonization in reality, the related analytical framework allows to analyze both types of convergence for cross-sectional data (GDP p.c. or another economic variable, yy, for ii regions and two points in time, tt and t+Tt+T), or one starting point (tt) and the average growth within the following nn years (t+1,t+2,...,t+nt+1, t+2, ..., t+n), respectively. Beta convergence can be calculated either in a linearized OLS regression model or in a nonlinear regression model. When no other variables are integrated in this model, it is called absolute beta convergence. Implementing other region-related variables (conditions) into the model leads to conditional beta convergence. If there is beta convergence (β<0\beta < 0), it is possible to calculate the speed of convergence, λ\lambda, and the so-called Half-Life HH, while the latter is the time taken to reduce the disparities by one half (Allington/McCombie 2007, Goecke/Huether 2016). There is sigma convergence, when the dispersion of the variable (σ\sigma), e.g. calculated as standard deviation or coefficient of variation, reduces from tt to t+Tt+T. This can be measured using ANOVA for two years or trend regression with respect to several years (Furceri 2005, Goecke/Huether 2016).

This function calculates the standard deviation (or variance, coefficient of variation) for the GDP per capita (or another economic variable) for both years and executes an analysis of variance (ANOVA) for these deviation measures (year 1 divided by year 2, F-statistic). If σt1/σt2>0\sigma_t1/\sigma_t2 > 0, there is sigma convergence.

Value

Returns a matrix containing the standard deviations, their quotient and the results of the significance test (F-statistic).

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Allington, N. F. B./McCombie, J. S. L. (2007): “Economic growth and beta-convergence in the East European Transition Economies”. In: Arestis, P./Baddely, M./McCombie, J. S. L. (eds.): Economic Growth. New Directions in Theory and Policy. Cheltenham: Elgar. p. 200-222.

Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (2009): “Introduction: regional growth and development theories in the twenty-first century - recent theoretical advances and future challenges”. In: Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (eds.): Handbook of Regional Growth and Development Theories. Cheltenham: Elgar. p. 1-16.

Dapena, A. D./Vazquez, E. F./Morollon, F. R. (2016): “The role of spatial scale in regional convergence: the effect of MAUP in the estimation of beta-convergence equations”. In: The Annals of Regional Science, 56, 2, p. 473-489.

Furceri, D. (2005): “Beta and sigma-convergence: A mathematical relation of causality”. In: Economics Letters, 89, 2, p. 212-215.

Goecke, H./Huether, M. (2016): “Regional Convergence in Europe”. In: Intereconomics, 51, 3, p. 165-171.

Young, A. T./Higgins, M. J./Levy, D. (2008): “Sigma Convergence versus Beta Convergence: Evidence from U.S. County-Level Data”. In: Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 40, 5, p. 1083-1093.

See Also

rca, sigmaconv.t, betaconv.nls, betaconv.speed, cv, sd2, var2

Examples

data(G.counties.gdp)
# Loading GDP data for Germany (counties = Landkreise)

sigmaconv (G.counties.gdp$gdppc2010, 2010, G.counties.gdp$gdppc2011, 2011, 
sigma.measure = "cv", print.results =  TRUE)
# Using the coefficient of variation

sigmaconv (G.counties.gdp$gdppc2010, 2010, G.counties.gdp$gdppc2011, 2011, 
sigma.log = TRUE, print.results =  TRUE)
# Using the standard deviation with logged GDP per capita

Analysis of regional sigma convergence for a time series using trend regression

Description

This function provides the analysis of regional economic sigma convergence (decline of deviation) for a time series using a trend regression

Usage

sigmaconv.t(gdp1, time1, gdp2, time2, sigma.measure = "sd", sigma.log = TRUE, 
sigma.weighting = NULL, sigma.issample = FALSE, 
sigma.plot = FALSE, sigma.plotLSize = 1, sigma.plotLineCol = "black", 
sigma.plotRLine = FALSE, sigma.plotRLineCol = "blue", 
sigma.Ymin = 0, sigma.plotX = "Time", sigma.plotY = "Variation", 
sigma.plotTitle = "Sigma convergence", sigma.bgCol = "gray95", sigma.bgrid = TRUE, 
sigma.bgridCol = "white", sigma.bgridSize = 2, sigma.bgridType = "solid", 
print.results = FALSE)

Arguments

gdp1

A numeric vector containing the GDP per capita (or another economic variable) at time t

time1

A single value of time t (= the initial year)

gdp2

A data frame containing the GDPs per capita (or another economic variable) at time t+1, t+2, t+3, ..., t+n

time2

A single value of time t+1

sigma.measure

argument that indicates how the sigma convergence should be measured. The default is output = "sd", which means that the standard deviation is used. If output = "var" or output = "cv", the variance or the coefficient of variation is used, respectively.

sigma.log

Logical argument. Per default (sigma.log = TRUE), also in the sigma convergence analysis, the economic variables are transformed by natural logarithm. If the original values should be used, state sigma.log = FALSE

sigma.weighting

If the measure of statistical dispersion in the sigma convergence analysis (coefficient of variation or standard deviation) should be weighted, a weighting vector has to be stated

sigma.issample

Logical argument that indicates if the dataset is a sample or the population (default: is.sample = FALSE, so the denominator of variance is nn)

sigma.plot

Logical argument that indicates if a plot of sigma convergence has to be created

sigma.plotLSize

If sigma.plot = TRUE: Line size of the sigma convergence plot

sigma.plotLineCol

If sigma.plot = TRUE: Line color of the sigma convergence plot

sigma.plotRLine

If sigma.plot = TRUE: Logical argument that indicates if a regression line has to be added to the plot

sigma.plotRLineCol

If sigma.plot = TRUE and sigma.plotRLine = TRUE: Color of the regression line

sigma.Ymin

If sigma.plot = TRUE: start value of the Y axis in the plot

sigma.plotX

If sigma.plot = TRUE: Name of the X axis

sigma.plotY

If sigma.plot = TRUE: Name of the Y axis

sigma.plotTitle

If sigma.plot = TRUE: Title of the plot

sigma.bgCol

If sigma.plot = TRUE: Plot background color

sigma.bgrid

If sigma.plot = TRUE: Logical argument that indicates if the plot contains a grid

sigma.bgridCol

If sigma.plot = TRUE and sigma.bgrid = TRUE: Color of the grid

sigma.bgridSize

If sigma.plot = TRUE and sigma.bgrid = TRUE: Size of the grid

sigma.bgridType

If sigma.plot = TRUE and sigma.bgrid = TRUE: Type of the grid

print.results

Logical argument that indicates if the function shows the results or not

Details

From the regional economic perspective (in particular the neoclassical growth theory), regional disparities are expected to decline. This convergence can have different meanings: Sigma convergence (σ\sigma) means a harmonization of regional economic output or income over time, while beta convergence (β\beta) means a decline of dispersion because poor regions have a stronger economic growth than rich regions (Capello/Nijkamp 2009). Regardless of the theoretical assumptions of a harmonization in reality, the related analytical framework allows to analyze both types of convergence for cross-sectional data (GDP p.c. or another economic variable, yy, for ii regions and two points in time, tt and t+Tt+T), or one starting point (tt) and the average growth within the following nn years (t+1,t+2,...,t+nt+1, t+2, ..., t+n), respectively. Beta convergence can be calculated either in a linearized OLS regression model or in a nonlinear regression model. When no other variables are integrated in this model, it is called absolute beta convergence. Implementing other region-related variables (conditions) into the model leads to conditional beta convergence. If there is beta convergence (β<0\beta < 0), it is possible to calculate the speed of convergence, λ\lambda, and the so-called Half-Life HH, while the latter is the time taken to reduce the disparities by one half (Allington/McCombie 2007, Goecke/Huether 2016). There is sigma convergence, when the dispersion of the variable (σ\sigma), e.g. calculated as standard deviation or coefficient of variation, reduces from tt to t+Tt+T. This can be measured using ANOVA for two years or trend regression with respect to several years (Furceri 2005, Goecke/Huether 2016).

This function calculates the standard deviation (or variance, coefficient of variation) for all GDPs per capita (or another economic variable) for the given years and executes a trend regression for these deviation measures. If the slope of the trend regression is negative, there is sigma convergence.

Value

Returns a matrix containing the trend regression model and the resulting significance tests (F-statistic, t-statistic).

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Allington, N. F. B./McCombie, J. S. L. (2007): “Economic growth and beta-convergence in the East European Transition Economies”. In: Arestis, P./Baddely, M./McCombie, J. S. L. (eds.): Economic Growth. New Directions in Theory and Policy. Cheltenham: Elgar. p. 200-222.

Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (2009): “Introduction: regional growth and development theories in the twenty-first century - recent theoretical advances and future challenges”. In: Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (eds.): Handbook of Regional Growth and Development Theories. Cheltenham: Elgar. p. 1-16.

Dapena, A. D./Vazquez, E. F./Morollon, F. R. (2016): “The role of spatial scale in regional convergence: the effect of MAUP in the estimation of beta-convergence equations”. In: The Annals of Regional Science, 56, 2, p. 473-489.

Furceri, D. (2005): “Beta and sigma-convergence: A mathematical relation of causality”. In: Economics Letters, 89, 2, p. 212-215.

Goecke, H./Huether, M. (2016): “Regional Convergence in Europe”. In: Intereconomics, 51, 3, p. 165-171.

Young, A. T./Higgins, M. J./Levy, D. (2008): “Sigma Convergence versus Beta Convergence: Evidence from U.S. County-Level Data”. In: Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 40, 5, p. 1083-1093.

See Also

rca, sigmaconv, betaconv.nls, betaconv.speed, cv, sd2, var2

Examples

data(G.counties.gdp)
# Loading GDP data for Germany (counties = Landkreise)

# Sigma convergence 2010-2014:
sigmaconv.t (G.counties.gdp$gdppc2010, 2010, G.counties.gdp[65:68], 2014, 
sigma.plot = TRUE, print.results = TRUE)
# Using the standard deviation with logged GDP per capita

sigmaconv.t (G.counties.gdp$gdppc2010, 2010, G.counties.gdp[65:68], 2014, 
sigma.measure = "cv", sigma.log = FALSE, print.results = TRUE)
# Using the coefficient of variation (GDP per capita not logged)

Measures of regional specialization

Description

Calculating three measures of regional specialization (Gini, Krugman, Hoover) for a set of JJ regions

Usage

spec(e_ij, industry.id, region.id, na.rm = TRUE)

Arguments

e_ij

a numeric vector with the employment of the industry ii in region jj

industry.id

a vector containing the IDs of the industries ii

region.id

a vector containing the IDs of the regions jj

na.rm

logical argument that indicates whether NA values should be excluded before computing results

Details

This function is a convenient wrapper for all functions calculating measures of regional specialization (Gini, Krugman, Hoover)

Value

A matrix with three columns (Gini coefficient, Krugman coefficient, Hoover coefficient) and JJ rows (one for each regarded region).

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Farhauer, O./Kroell, A. (2014): “Standorttheorien: Regional- und Stadtoekonomik in Theorie und Praxis”. Wiesbaden : Springer.

Schaetzl, L. (2000): “Wirtschaftsgeographie 2: Empirie”. Paderborn : Schoeningh.

See Also

gini.spec, krugman.spec2, hoover

Examples

data(G.regions.industries)

spec_j <- spec (e_ij = G.regions.industries$emp_all, 
industry.id = G.regions.industries$ind_code,
region.id = G.regions.industries$region_code)

Theil inequality index

Description

Calculating the Theil inequality index

Usage

theil(x, weighting = NULL, na.rm = TRUE)

Arguments

x

a numeric vector

weighting

a numeric weighting vector, e.g. population

na.rm

logical argument that indicates whether NA values should be excluded before computing results

Details

Since there are several Theil measures of inequality, this function uses the formulation from Stoermann (2009).

Value

A single numeric value of the Theil inequality index (0<TI<10 < TI < 1).

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Portnov, B.A./Felsenstein, D. (2010): “On the suitability of income inequality measures for regional analysis: Some evidence from simulation analysis and bootstrapping tests”. In: Socio-Economic Planning Sciences, 44, 4, p. 212-219.

Stoermann, W. (2009): “Regionaloekonomik: Theorie und Politik”. Muenchen : Oldenbourg.

See Also

gini, herf, hoover

Examples

# Example from Stoermann (2009):
regincome <- c(10,10,10,20,50)
theil(regincome) 
# 0.2326302

Creating dummy variables

Description

This function creates a dataset of dummy variables based on an input character vector.

Usage

to.dummy(x)

Arguments

x

A character vector

Details

This function transforms a character vector x with cc characteristics to a set of cc dummy variables whose column names corresponding to these characteristics marked with “_DUMMY”.

Value

A data.frame with dummy variables corresponding to the levels of the input variable.

Note

This function contains code from the authors' package MCI.

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Greene, W. H. (2012): “Econometric Analysis”. 7th edition. Harlow : Pearson.

Examples

charvec <- c("Peter", "Paul", "Peter", "Mary", "Peter", "Paul")
# Creates a vector with three names (Peter, Paul, Mary)
to.dummy(charvec)
# Returns a data frame with 3 dummy variables
# (Mary_DUMMY, Paul_DUMMY, Peter_DUMMY)

Variance (extended)

Description

Calculating the variance (var), weighted or non-weighted, for samples or populations

Usage

var2(x, is.sample = TRUE, weighting = NULL, wmean = FALSE, na.rm = TRUE)

Arguments

x

a numeric vector

is.sample

logical argument that indicates if the dataset is a sample or the population (default: is.sample = TRUE, so the denominator of variance is n1n-1)

weighting

a numeric vector containing weighting data to compute the weighted standard deviation (instead of the non-weighted sd)

wmean

logical argument that indicates if the weighted mean is used when calculating the weighted standard deviation

na.rm

logical argument that whether NA values should be extracted or not

Details

The function calculates the variance (var). Unlike the R base var function, the var2 function allows to choose if the data is treated as sample (denominator of variance is n1n-1)) or not (denominator of variance is nn))

From a regional economic perspective, var and sd is closely linked to the concept of sigma convergence (σ\sigma) which means a harmonization of regional economic output or income over time, while the other type of convergence, beta convergence (β\beta), means a decline of dispersion because poor regions have a stronger growth than rich regions (Capello/Nijkamp 2009). The sd allows to summarize regional disparities (e.g. disparities in regional GDP per capita) in one indicator. The coefficient of variation (see the function cv) is more frequently used for this purpose (e.g. Lessmann 2005, Huang/Leung 2009, Siljak 2015). But the sd can also be used for any other types of disparities or dispersion, such as disparities in supply (e.g. density of physicians or grocery stores).

The variance can be weighted by using a second weighting vector. As there is more than one way to weight measures of statistical dispersion, this function uses the formula for the weighted variance (σw\sigma_w) from Sheret (1984). The vector x is automatically treated as a sample (such as in the base sd function), so the denominator of variance is n1n-1, if it is not, set is.sample = FALSE.

Value

Single numeric value. If weighting is specified, the function returns a weighted variance (optionally using a weighted arithmetic mean if wmean = TRUE).

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Bahrenberg, G./Giese, E./Mevenkamp, N./Nipper, J. (2010): “Statistische Methoden in der Geographie. Band 1: Univariate und bivariate Statistik”. Stuttgart: Borntraeger.

Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (2009): “Introduction: regional growth and development theories in the twenty-first century - recent theoretical advances and future challenges”. In: Capello, R./Nijkamp, P. (eds.): Handbook of Regional Growth and Development Theories. Cheltenham: Elgar. p. 1-16.

Lessmann, C. (2005): “Regionale Disparitaeten in Deutschland und ausgesuchten OECD-Staaten im Vergleich”. ifo Dresden berichtet, 3/2005. https://www.ifo.de/DocDL/ifodb_2005_3_25-33.pdf.

Huang, Y./Leung, Y. (2009): “Measuring Regional Inequality: A Comparison of Coefficient of Variation and Hoover Concentration Index”. In: The Open Geography Journal, 2, p. 25-34.

Sheret, M. (1984): “The Coefficient of Variation: Weighting Considerations”. In: Social Indicators Research, 15, 3, p. 289-295.

Siljak, D. (2015): “Real Economic Convergence in Western Europe from 1995 to 2013”. In: International Journal of Business and Economic Development, 3, 3, p. 56-67.

See Also

sd2, cv, gini, herf, hoover, mean2, rca

Examples

# Regional disparities / sigma convergence in Germany
data(G.counties.gdp)
# GDP per capita for German counties (Landkreise)
vars <- apply (G.counties.gdp[54:68], MARGIN = 2, FUN = var2)
# Calculating variance for the years 2000-2014
years <- 2000:2014
plot(years, vars, "l", xlab = "year", 
ylab = "Variance of GDP per capita")
# Plot variance over time

Williamson index

Description

Calculating the Williamson index (population-weighted coefficient of variation)

Usage

williamson (x, weighting, coefnorm = FALSE, wmean = FALSE, na.rm = TRUE)

Arguments

x

a numeric vector

weighting

mandatory: a numeric vector containing weighting data (usually regional population)

coefnorm

logical argument that indicates if the function output is the standardized cv (0<v<10 < v* < 1) or not (0<v<0 < v < \infty) (default: coefnorm = FALSE)

wmean

logical argument that indicates if the weighted mean is used when calculating the weighted coefficient of variation

na.rm

logical argument that whether NA values should be extracted or not

Details

The Williamson index (Williamson 1965) is a population-weighted coefficient of variation.

The coefficient of variation, vv, is a dimensionless measure of statistical dispersion (0<v<0 < v < \infty), based on variance and standard deviation, respectively. The cv (variance, standard deviation) can be weighted by using a second weighting vector. As there is more than one way to weight measures of statistical dispersion, this function uses the formula for the weighted cv (vwv_w) from Sheret (1984). The cv can be standardized, while this function uses the formula for the standardized cv (vv*, with 0<v<10 < v* < 1) from Kohn/Oeztuerk (2013). The vector x is automatically treated as a sample (such as in the base sd function), so the denominator of variance is n1n-1, if it is not, set is.sample = FALSE.

Value

Single numeric value. If coefnorm = FALSE the function returns the non-standardized cv (0<v<0 < v < \infty). If coefnorm = TRUE the standardized cv (0<v<10 < v* < 1) is returned.

Author(s)

Thomas Wieland

References

Gluschenko, K. (2018): “Measuring regional inequality: to weight or not to weight?” In: Spatial Economic Analysis, 13, 1, p. 36-59.

Lessmann, C. (2005): “Regionale Disparitaeten in Deutschland und ausgesuchten OECD-Staaten im Vergleich”. ifo Dresden berichtet, 3/2005. https://www.ifo.de/DocDL/ifodb_2005_3_25-33.pdf.

Huang, Y./Leung, Y. (2009): “Measuring Regional Inequality: A Comparison of Coefficient of Variation and Hoover Concentration Index”. In: The Open Geography Journal, 2, p. 25-34.

Kohn, W./Oeztuerk, R. (2013): “Statistik fuer Oekonomen. Datenanalyse mit R und SPSS”. Berlin: Springer.

Portnov, B.A./Felsenstein, D. (2010): “On the suitability of income inequality measures for regional analysis: Some evidence from simulation analysis and bootstrapping tests”. In: Socio-Economic Planning Sciences, 44, 4, p. 212-219.

Sheret, M. (1984): “The Coefficient of Variation: Weighting Considerations”. In: Social Indicators Research, 15, 3, p. 289-295.

Williamson, J. G. (1965): “Regional Inequality and the Process of National Development: A Description of the Patterns”. In: Economic Development and Cultural Change, 13, 4/2, p. 1-84.

See Also

gini, herf, hoover, cv, disp

Examples

data(GoettingenHealth2)
# districts with healthcare providers and population size

williamson((GoettingenHealth2$phys_gen/GoettingenHealth2$pop), 
GoettingenHealth2$pop)